Whatever Happened To The Bismarckian Welfare State? From .

2y ago
91 Views
2 Downloads
293.79 KB
34 Pages
Last View : 1m ago
Last Download : 3m ago
Upload by : Camryn Boren
Transcription

DISCUSSION PAPER SERIESIZA DP No. 4085Whatever Happened to the Bismarckian Welfare State?From Labor Shedding to Employment-Friendly ReformsAnton HemerijckWerner EichhorstMarch 2009Forschungsinstitutzur Zukunft der ArbeitInstitute for the Studyof Labor

Whatever Happened to the BismarckianWelfare State? From Labor Shedding toEmployment-Friendly ReformsAnton HemerijckFree University Amsterdamand Erasmus University RotterdamWerner EichhorstIZADiscussion Paper No. 4085March 2009IZAP.O. Box 724053072 BonnGermanyPhone: 49-228-3894-0Fax: 49-228-3894-180E-mail: iza@iza.orgAny opinions expressed here are those of the author(s) and not those of IZA. Research published inthis series may include views on policy, but the institute itself takes no institutional policy positions.The Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA) in Bonn is a local and virtual international research centerand a place of communication between science, politics and business. IZA is an independent nonprofitorganization supported by Deutsche Post Foundation. The center is associated with the University ofBonn and offers a stimulating research environment through its international network, workshops andconferences, data service, project support, research visits and doctoral program. IZA engages in (i)original and internationally competitive research in all fields of labor economics, (ii) development ofpolicy concepts, and (iii) dissemination of research results and concepts to the interested public.IZA Discussion Papers often represent preliminary work and are circulated to encourage discussion.Citation of such a paper should account for its provisional character. A revised version may beavailable directly from the author.

IZA Discussion Paper No. 4085March 2009ABSTRACTWhatever Happened to the Bismarckian Welfare State?From Labor Shedding to Employment-Friendly ReformsThe paper challenges the widespread view that Bismarckian countries with a strong role ofsocial insurance and labor market regulation are less successful than other employmentregimes and hard to reforms. This has been true about a decade ago. But both theinstitutional set-up and the performance of BIsmarckian countries have changedfundamentally over the last years. The paper summarizes major reform dynamics inBismarckian welfare states which had adopted a strategy of labor shedding in the 1970s and1980s to combat open unemployment. As this was associated with an increasing burden ofnon-wage labor costs, this triggered a sequence of more employment-oriented and morefundamental reforms that eventually helped overcome a low employment situation. The paperpursues the trajectory of reforms, shows the structural change in labor market performanceand points out the achievements of past reforms, but also emphasizes the need for furtheraction in terms of education and training, activation and employment opportunities for allworking age people in these countries so that flexibility and security can be reconciled.JEL Classification:Keywords:J26, J68Bismarckian welfare states, social insurance, social policy, employment,labor market policiesCorresponding author:Werner EichhorstIZAP.O. Box 7240D-53072 BonnGermanyE-mail: eichhorst@iza.org

2X.1 The adaptive capacity of the continental welfare stateIs the welfare state fit for the 21st century? This question has haunted European policymakers and researchers for over a decade. Sluggish growth and weak job creation around theturn of the new millennium has not only given way to a fierce ideological battle betweendifferent socio-economic ‘models’, triggering political strife and separating antagonisticadvocacy coalitions – but also contributed to a strand of analytical literature pointing out thestructural impediments to ‘modernize’ Continental European and Mediterranean welfarestates and make them both more employment friendly and sustainable (see e.g. Scharpf andSchmidt 2000). The Bismarckian version of the European social model was pitted against afalse stereotype of the ‘Anglo-Saxon’ model of capitalism, allegedly a ‘free market without asafety net’, producing high levels of poverty and inequality, but also against Scandinavianwelfare states with universal benefits and strong public services in education, child-care andactive labor market policies.Rather than extrapolating policy recipes from recent economic performance, urgingEuropean OECD members to recast their social market economies along the lines ofAmerican capitalism, a more illuminating way to understand recent reform dynamics is tocontextualize existing social policy repertoires and reform dynamics in the face of thechanging economic and technological challenges and evolving social and demographicstructures. As shown in the various chapters of this book, the striking intensity and thecomprehensive character of social and economic policy reform across the majority of the socalled Bismarckian welfare regimes, including the six founding EU Member States ofGermany, France, Italy and the Benelux countries, together with the later entrants Spain andAustria as well as the Visegrad countries (the Czech Republic, Slovakia, Hungary and Poland)and Switzerland, since the mid-1990s, is very much at odds with a prevalent image of a‘frozen welfare landscape’ in the academic literature. Most important, the substantive extentof welfare redirection across a large number of Member States of the European Union (EU)adds up to the momentum of substantive policy change and goes far beyond the popularconcepts of ‘retrenchment’ and ‘roll-back.’ But to say that the Bismarckian welfare states, ascompared the Anglo-Irish and Scandinavian welfare regimes, are far from sclerotic is not tosay that they are in good shape.Today four sets of challenges confront policy makers with the imperative to redirect thewelfare effort, to redesign institutions and to elaborate on new principles of social justice.From without, in the first place, international competition is challenging the redistributivescope and de-commodifying power of the national welfare state. Many academic observersbelieve that the increase in cross-border competition in the markets for money, goods andservices has substantially reduced the room for maneuver of national welfare states (Scharpf

ercyclicalmacroeconomicmanagement, while increased openness exposes generous welfare states to trade competitionand permits capital to move to the lowest-cost producer countries. Finally, there is the dangerthat tax competition will result in the under-provision of public goods.Second, from within, ageing populations, declining birth rates, changing gender roles inhouseholds as a result of the mass entry of women to the labor market, the shift from anindustrial to the service economy, new technologies in the organization of work, engendersub-optimal employment levels, new inequalities and human capital-biased patterns of socialexclusion. Skills-biased technological change, the feminization of the labor market, anddemographic ageing, as a result of rising life expectancy and rapidly falling birth rates, arethe most important drivers of the new post-industrial risk profile. While the boundariesbetween being ‘in’ and ‘out’ of work have been blurred by increases in atypical work, lowwages, subsidized jobs, and training programs, one job is no longer enough to keep lowincome families out of poverty. According to Gøsta Esping-Andersen et al (2002), the mostimportant reason why the existing systems of social care have become overstretched stemsfrom the weakening of labor markets and family households as traditional providers ofwelfare. In addition, new sources of immigration and segregation, especially in the housingmarket in metropolitan areas, pose a challenge to social cohesion. The present economiccrisis is likely to pose new forms of segmentation on the labor markets to the detriment of themost vulnerable groups such as agency workers, fixed-term employees and the unemployedwhile labor market insiders have less to fear. Hence, risks and capacities to adapt aredistributed unequally across the labor force.And while policy makers must find new ways to manage the adverse consequences ofeconomic internationalization and post-industrial differentiation, their endeavor to recast thewelfare state is severely constrained by long standing social policy commitments in the areasof unemployment and pensions, which have ushered in a period of permanent austerity(Pierson 1998, 2001A). The maturation of welfare commitments, policies put in place to caterafter the social risks associated with the post-war industrial era now seem to crowd out andoverload the available policy space for effective policy responses in especially public servicesunder conditions of low economic growth. This specter of permanent austerity is likely tointensify in the face of population ageing. Although in the current downturn manygovernments switch to public spending in order to reflate the economy, this may generateadditional fiscal pressures in the foreseeable future.Finally, as an intervening variable in the process, issues of work and welfare have becomeever more intertwined with processes of European political and economic integration sincethe 1980s. It is fair to say that in the EU we have entered an era of semi-sovereign welfarestates (Leibfried and Pierson 2000). European economic integration has fundamentally

4recast the boundaries of national systems of employment regulation and social protection,both by constraining autonomy for domestic policy options but also by opening opportunitiesfor EU-led social and employment coordination and agenda setting (Ferrera 2005; Zeitlin2005). The introduction of the internal market and the introduction of the EMU, andStability and Growth Pact, have added a new economic supranational layer to domestic socialand economic policy repertoires of individual Member States. Since the mid-1990s, the EUhas taken on a far more pro-active role as a central social policy agenda setter. The EuropeanEmployment Strategy, based on the new Employment Title of the Amsterdam Treaty,launched in 1997, is exemplary of the EU’s new role of agenda setting policy coordination,designed to catalyze rather than steer domestic social policy reform.Although all European welfare states face the challenges of economic internationalization,post-industrial societal change, and intensified European integration under conditions ofrelative macroeconomic austerity, comparative research reveals how internal and externalchallenges confront different clusters of welfare regimes with a distinct constellation ofadjustment problems and reform agendas. It has often been argued that the institutionalconfiguration of Continental welfare states, with their traditional Bismarckian labor marketand social policy legacies, with its strong bias towards the protection of the steadyemployment of male breadwinners, are, in comparison to the Anglo-Saxon social model andthe Scandinavians worlds of welfare, the most difficult to reform. In spite of the obvious‘irresistible forces’ urging for reform, the Continental welfare model has remained an‘unmovable object’ (Pierson 1998). Especially the larger political economies of France,Germany and Italy, are often mocked for their ‘frozen fordism’, ‘inactivity traps’, ‘welfarewithout work’ conundrum and ‘insider-outsider’ segmentation, ‘perverse familialism’ and‘permanent pension crises’ (Palier and Martin 2007). With the Bismarckian regime typecovering a large majority of EU Member States, this is all the more problematic for the EUaspiring to become – following the Lisbon agenda – the most competitive knowledge-basedeconomy in the world.As the series of fresh and detailed analyses of reforms implemented in Bismarckianwelfare systems published in this volume show, the pace and scope of Continental welfarereform is more profound, even if incomplete, than is suggested in the literature on the ‘newpolitics of the welfare state’. To be sure, the Continental reform momentum is very rooted inthe incongruence between new economic and social contexts and institutional resilience ofBismarckian male-breadwinner social policy provisions, based on occupationally distinct,employment-related social insurance principles, underpinned by traditional (singlebreadwinner) family values (Esping-Andersen 1990; Ferrera 1998; Scharpf and Schmidt2000; Ferrera, Hemerijck and Rhodes 2000; Palier 2006). Catching up with the moreemployment and family-friendly Scandinavian and Anglo-Saxon welfare state has been

5particularly difficult for Continental welfare states, as will be surveyed below. The slow butfundamental departure from ‘welfare without work’ strategy in Continental welfare systemssince the mid-1990s is best understood as a profound transformative process of policy changeacross a number of intimately related policy domains. However, the reform sequence that ledto ever more fundamental transformations of the Bismarckian edifice began even earlier inthe 1970s with a first wave of retrenchment that eventually paved the way for more farreaching institutional and later structural reforms. Through a more or less protractedsequence of reforms, Bismarckian welfare states shifted from labor shedding to policies thataim at mobilizing labor supply as well as labor demand. Employment friendly policiesreplaced mainly social policy approaches to unemployment. By deliberately begging thequestion of Continental welfare inertia, this contribution focuses on the adaptive capacity ofEurope’s Bismarckian welfare states to the challenges of economic internationalization andpost-industrial differentiation, and permanent austerity in the shadow of intensifiedEuropean (economic) integration.The argument is constructed as follows. First, Section 2 renders an inventory ofcomparative employment so as to highlight the particular weaknesses of the Bismarck-typewelfare regime, together with its recent improvements, in comparison to other Europeanwelfare state families. Next, section 3 turns a diachronic qualitative analysis of the sequenceand scope of employment-friendly reforms in different policy areas within and acrossdifferent Bismarckian welfare systems. This overview will reveal how much the 1990s andearly 2000s has been an epoch of intense policy change in the make up Europe’s Bismarckianwelfare states. To say that the Continental welfare state is far from sclerotic is not to say thatthey are in good shape. In conclusion, Section 4 highlights, by employing a life courseperspective, what we think is the unfinished social reform agenda for most Continentalwelfare states still today.X.2 The continental employment dilemmaEmployment is the most important measure for judging the sustainability of the Continentalwelfare state and the success of social and economic policy reform. The reason for this issimple: benefits and social services have to be paid by the taxes and social securitycontributions from those in work. The more working people there are, the broader thisfunding base is. In the event of long-term unemployment, incapacity to work and earlyretirement, spending on social security goes up while at the same time revenues fall. From asociological perspective, having a job also benefits people by giving them enhancedopportunities for self-actualization and self-esteem. Participating in the labor market is today

6the most important form of social interaction and, as such, is an indispensable element inachieving social cohesion.The response of the Continental and Mediterranean welfare states to the process ofeconomic restructuring in the 1970s and 1980s, but also the policy applied by the transitioncountries in the early 1990s was aimed at keeping open unemployment low by limiting laborsupply. Most Continental welfare states began using disability pensions, early retirement,and long-term unemployment schemes to remove older and less productive workers from thelabor market. Luring people out of the labor market by facilitating early retirement,increasing benefits for the long-term unemployed, lifting the obligation of job search forolder workers, discouraging mothers from job search, favoring long periods of leave, easingthe access to disability pensions and reducing working hours, all contributed to thecharacteristically Continental ‘welfare without work’ policy strategy that became popular inthe 1980s and for most of the 1990s (Esping-Andersen, 1996). Growing demands on socialsecurity led to burgeoning costs to be borne by the labor market. From the middle of the1980s onwards, employers in Continental welfare states increasingly began using laborsaving technology and shedding less productive employees via the social security system.This turned the Continental productivity squeeze into an inactivity trap. A vicious cycle aroseof high gross wage costs, low net wages, the exit of less productive workers and rising socialcosts, creating a spiral of falling employment and rising economic inactivity. This alsoundermined the financial basis of the social security system. In addition, strict employmentregulation, including minimum wages and hiring and firing restrictions, protected theinsiders in key industries, while harming the participation of outsiders, youngsters, women,older workers, low skill groups and ethnic minorities (Hemerijck, van Kersbergen, andManow 2000).From the 1990s onwards the policy of labor supply reduction came to be brandished as apolicy failure and, if continued uncorrected, as a threat to the survival of the welfare state.Towards the mid-1990s, the Continental or Bismarckian employment deficit triggered animportant shift in the definition of the crisis of the Continental welfare state away from earlyexit adjustment strategies. Policy makers came to realize that the low level of labor marketparticipation was the Achilles’ heel of the Continental welfare state. This diagnosis initiated aseries of reforms intended to overcome male-breadwinner policy provisions and to correct forpast early exit policy mistakes in many areas of social and economic regulation, includingcollective bargaining, social security, labor market policy and regulation, pensions and socialservices, including health and education. To be sure, at times these reforms met with stiffresistance from the social partners, especially the trade unions, defending their privilegedposition in Bismarckian social insurance administration with its tradition of associational

7self-regulation by the social partners, as a corollary of the payroll financing of the Continentalwelfare state.In part as a result of these reforms, since the mid-1990s, there has been a significantincrease in employment across virtually all mature European welfare states over the lastdecade (Eichhorst and Hemerijck 2008). Figure X.1 shows the employment/populationratios among people in the working age population. What is striking is, first, the long-termincrease in employment in most countries and, second, some persistent differences in theoverall share of people in gainful employment across countries and families of welfare states.We can see substantial gains over the last decade, in particular in traditional low and mediumemployment countries. Except for three transition countries, all Bismarckian welfare statesexperienced job growth. It was most pronounced in the Netherlands and Spain, but leincreasesintheemployment/population ratio so that employment rates across Europe converged to a certainextent. The Bismarckian cluster can no longer be described as a group of countries with a lowemployment level. In fact, Switzerland and the Netherlands join Sweden and Denmark as thegroup with the highest employment rates whereas Austria, the Czech Republic and Germanyare above the EU-27 average and France, Belgium, Italy and Hungary approached this valueconsiderably

welfare effort, to redesign institutions and to elaborate on new principles of social justice. From without, in the first place, international competition is challenging the redistributive scope and de-commodifying power of the nationa

Related Documents:

May 02, 2018 · D. Program Evaluation ͟The organization has provided a description of the framework for how each program will be evaluated. The framework should include all the elements below: ͟The evaluation methods are cost-effective for the organization ͟Quantitative and qualitative data is being collected (at Basics tier, data collection must have begun)

Silat is a combative art of self-defense and survival rooted from Matay archipelago. It was traced at thé early of Langkasuka Kingdom (2nd century CE) till thé reign of Melaka (Malaysia) Sultanate era (13th century). Silat has now evolved to become part of social culture and tradition with thé appearance of a fine physical and spiritual .

On an exceptional basis, Member States may request UNESCO to provide thé candidates with access to thé platform so they can complète thé form by themselves. Thèse requests must be addressed to esd rize unesco. or by 15 A ril 2021 UNESCO will provide thé nomineewith accessto thé platform via their émail address.

̶The leading indicator of employee engagement is based on the quality of the relationship between employee and supervisor Empower your managers! ̶Help them understand the impact on the organization ̶Share important changes, plan options, tasks, and deadlines ̶Provide key messages and talking points ̶Prepare them to answer employee questions

Dr. Sunita Bharatwal** Dr. Pawan Garga*** Abstract Customer satisfaction is derived from thè functionalities and values, a product or Service can provide. The current study aims to segregate thè dimensions of ordine Service quality and gather insights on its impact on web shopping. The trends of purchases have

Chính Văn.- Còn đức Thế tôn thì tuệ giác cực kỳ trong sạch 8: hiện hành bất nhị 9, đạt đến vô tướng 10, đứng vào chỗ đứng của các đức Thế tôn 11, thể hiện tính bình đẳng của các Ngài, đến chỗ không còn chướng ngại 12, giáo pháp không thể khuynh đảo, tâm thức không bị cản trở, cái được

8 Finally, brothers, whatever is true, whatever is noble, whatever is right, whatever is pure, whatever is lovely, whatever is admirable-if anything is excellent or praiseworthy-think about such things. 9 Whatever you have learned or received or heard from me, or seen in me-put

May 25, 2017 · “Finally, brothers and sisters, whatever is true, whatever is noble, whatever is right, whatever is pure, whatever is lovely, whatever is admirable—if anything is excellent or praiseworthy—think about such things. Whatever you have learned or received or heard from me, or seen in