Firm Input Choice Under Trade Policy Uncertainty

2y ago
121 Views
2 Downloads
689.65 KB
67 Pages
Last View : 1m ago
Last Download : 3m ago
Upload by : Brady Himes
Transcription

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIESFIRM INPUT CHOICE UNDER TRADE POLICY UNCERTAINTYKyle HandleyNuno LimãoRodney D. LudemaZhi YuWorking Paper 27910http://www.nber.org/papers/w27910NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH1050 Massachusetts AvenueCambridge, MA 02138October 2020We received helpful comments and questions from Ben Faber, Deborah Swenson, Daniel Xu,Eunhee Lee, Fernando Parro, George Alessandria, Jim Tybout, Jonathan Eaton, MeredithCrowley, Robert Staiger, Samuel Kortum, Shafaat Khan and various seminar and conferenceparticipants at Kobe, Stanford, Penn State, the AEA Meetings, Washington Area InternationalTrade Symposium, International Trade Dynamics Workshop and NBER International TradePolicy and Institutions. Zhi Yu acknowledges support from the Public Computing Cloud Platformat Renmin University of China. The views expressed herein are those of the authors and do notnecessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research.NBER working papers are circulated for discussion and comment purposes. They have not beenpeer-reviewed or been subject to the review by the NBER Board of Directors that accompaniesofficial NBER publications. 2020 by Kyle Handley, Nuno Limão, Rodney D. Ludema, and Zhi Yu. All rights reserved.Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permissionprovided that full credit, including notice, is given to the source.

Firm Input Choice Under Trade Policy UncertaintyKyle Handley, Nuno Limão, Rodney D. Ludema, and Zhi YuNBER Working Paper No. 27910October 2020JEL No. F02,F1,F12,F13,F14,F61,O19,O24ABSTRACTWe examine the role of trade policy uncertainty in shaping the import decisions of firms. If theadoption of a new input requires a sunk cost investment, then the prospect of price increases inthat input, e.g. due to trade barriers, reduces the adoption of that input (a substitution effect) andpossibly other inputs (complementarity via lower profits). Thus trade policy uncertainty canaffect a firm’s entire input mix. We provide a new model of input price uncertainty that capturesboth effects and derive its empirical implications. We test these using an important episode thatlowered input price uncertainty: China’s accession to the WTO and the associated commitment tobind its import tariffs. We estimate large increases in imported inputs by firms from accession;the reduced uncertainty from commitment generates substitution effects larger than the reductionsin applied tariffs in 2000-2006 and has significant profit effects.Kyle HandleyRoss School of BusinessUniversity of Michigan701 Tappan StreetAnn Arbor, MI 48109and NBERhandleyk@umich.eduNuno LimãoDepartment of EconomicsUniversity of Maryland3105 Tydings HallCollege Park, MD 20742and NBERlimao@econ.umd.eduRodney D. LudemaGeorgetown Universityludemar@georgetown.eduZhi YuRenmin University of Chinayuzhi@rmbs.ruc.edu.cn

1IntroductionWe examine the role of policy uncertainty in shaping the input decisions of rms. If newinputs require a sunk cost investment, then rm decisions to adopt them depend on howuncertain their prices are. One such source of uncertainty is future policy, e.g. taxes ondomestic or imported inputs, that a ects the level and mix of inputs the rm adopts. Wedevelop a theoretical model of this phenomenon and test its key implications using rm dataon input usage and shocks to import taxes arising from China’s WTO accession.We build on and contribute to ongoing research on various important issues. First, thereis extensive research on global sourcing and the determinants of increased intermediate trade,but it has ignored the role of policy uncertainty. Intermediate inputs account for the bulkof world trade (Johnson and Noguera, 2012), and vertical specialization across countries isa prominent feature of the world economy (Hummels et al., 2001). Trade liberalization, inparticular, has been shown to be a major contributor to the growth in vertical specialization (Hanson et al., 2005; Johnson and Noguera, 2017) with important implications forproductivity and welfare (Amiti, and Konings, 2007; Goldberg et al., 2010; Halpern et al.,2015).Second, we contribute to the research on trade policy uncertainty (TPU) by movingits focus from exporting to global sourcing decisions. There is increasing evidence thatreductions in TPU increase trade (Crowley et al., 2018; Feng et al., 2017; Handley, 2014;Handley and Limão, 2015; Pierce and Schott, 2016). In these papers, because of sunk costs,the response of export decisions to a foreign tari reduction depends on rms’beliefs aboutwhether the policy change is permanent or reversible, and trade agreements play a role inshaping such beliefs.1 As Antràs, et al. (2017) note, sourcing is a more complex problemthan exporting in that it involves a portfolio of inputs with potential interactions betweenthem.We also contribute to the analysis of the role of international trade agreements. Existingtheories emphasize the role of agreements in addressing terms-of-trade externalities (Bagwelland Staiger, 1999; Grossman and Helpman, 1995), or allowing governments to commit visa-vis domestic actors (e.g. Maggi and Rodriguez-Clare, 1998) or reducing TPU (Limão andMaggi, 2015). There is increasing evidence for the terms-of-trade role of agreements (Broda,Limão, Weinstein, 2008; Bagwell and Staiger, 2011) but less so on own commitment e ects.Research on the e ect of TPU provides support for the idea that a country’s exportersbene t from agreements that tie the foreign governments hands. We provide theory and1Handley and Limão (2017) show this has important price and welfare e ects and extend this logic toentry and technology-upgrading decisions but not to global sourcing decisions. Uncertainty can also a ectexports via inventory e ects (Alessandria et al., 2019).

evidence that agreements provide a valuable commitment device to the importing country:by tying its own hands it spurs investment in the adoption of imported inputs. This suggestsan important cost of ongoing trade tensions that erode the credibility of the WTO. It alsopoints to a potential rationale for agreements on input trade.2Our empirical application contributes to the large literature examining the impressivegrowth in Chinese rm exports, imports and productivity after its 2001 WTO entry. Thiswork includes the e ects of reductions in Chinese applied tari s (Amiti et. al. 2018; Brandt,et. al., 2017; Feng et al., 2016; Yu, 2015) and reductions in U.S. TPU that Chinese exportersfaced in the U.S. (Feng et al., 2017; Handley and Limão, 2017; Pierce and Schott, 2016). Bothof these channels are potentially important for Chinese export outcomes.3 Our contributionhere is to go beyond the applied reductions in Chinese tari s and also estimate and quantifythe impact of its commitments not to reverse its liberalization on intermediate usage andadoption.Finally, by identifying how policy uncertainty a ects speci c rm investments we alsocontribute to research showing that economic uncertainty leads rms to delay investments(Bloom et al., 2007) and that policy uncertainty (measured by news indices) helps predictaggregate output declines (cf. Baker et al., 2016).In our model rms invest to adopt a range of intermediates used to produce a di erentiated product under uncertainty in input prices driven by policy, e.g. taxes. Similarlyto recent rm-based frameworks, greater input variety reduces the rms’marginal cost buteach variety requires a cost to adopt (c.f. Halpern et al., 2015; Antràs, et al., 2017; Blaum etal., 2018). Unlike such frameworks, we model adoption costs as sunk, which implies the rmsourcing decision is a dynamic one and introduces a role for policy uncertainty.4 We focuson shocks to relative prices between imported and domestic inputs arising from TPU, e.g.changes in the probability of tari increases. The reduction in TPU in an input leads to anincrease in its imports: a substitution e ect. Moreover, this reduction in TPU also increasesthe usage of other inputs: due to a pro t e ect, which gives rise to input complementarityin our setting.We use transactions-level trade data from 2000-2006 to examine how China’s WTO tari commitments a ected its rm’s imports of intermediates. After its economic reform andopening in the late 1970s, China applied to re-enter the GATT in 1986 and then its successor,2Such agreements may need to be deeper than the traditional ones focused on nal goods as Antras andStaiger (2012) show in a setting where imports of customized inputs generates bargaining externalities.3Amiti, et. al. (2018) nd that both lower Chinese input tari s and US TPU contributed to the reductionin their export prices to the US.4Gervais (2018) models and tests an alternative channel whereby more risk averse managers source fromlower price volatility input suppliers.2

the WTO, which it acceded in 2001. As we show in Figure 1 the average statutory importtari was over 40% when it applied and around 10% by 2006. Most research on the WTOimpact focuses on the tari reductions after 2000, but this is only about one third of theimport liberalization that occurs since 1992 (Lardy, 2002). The process since 1992 was drivenby the “Socialist Market Economy”reforms and arguably as a condition for WTO accession(cf. Tang and Wei, 2009). A similar pattern holds for intermediate products, as we see since1992. The outcome of this accession process was uncertain until 2001; and if China had notjoined then it could have reversed some of the earlier liberalization.5 This potential reversalhung over Chinese importers, just as the U.S. annual threat of removal of China’s MFNstatus hung over its exporters.If WTO accession increased the cost of reversing China’s tari reforms then our modelpredicts it should have increased imported input adoption. We rst provide descriptiveevidence that (i) 2/3 of that import growth is from new HS6 products, (ii) the fraction ofimporting rms increases, and (iii) there are sunk costs at the HS6 level. We then test themodel predictions by constructing the required measure of tari risk for imported inputs ineach HS6, which is the di erence between the historical mean tari dating back to 1992 andits respective current rate.The regression analysis, which controls for applied tari changes and various xed e ects,shows that this tari risk depressed Chinese rms’ imported intermediates prior to WTOentry, and that this e ect is sharply reduced after WTO entry, consistent with increasedcommitment. These results are robust to alternative rm samples, risk measures, sources ofTPU and explanations such as history dependence.We nd evidence consistent with several additional aspects of the model. First, theapplied tari trade elasticity increases substantially after WTO entry, suggesting that importers perceived them to be more permanent. Second, we identify both substitution andcomplementarity e ects. Third, the estimates vary with initial rm productivity. Finally,post-accession, rms were more likely to adopt products that were previously subject tohigher risk.There are important quantitative implications from these estimates. The probability ofreversal falls substantially— it is predicted to be less than 13 percent after accession. Weestimate that WTO accession increased average rm imported inputs about 92 lp between2000-2006. Over three quarters of this accession e ect is due to improved commitment viaboth substitution and complementarity e ects; the latter worked through an increase in5Several events contributed to this uncertainty including the death of Deng Xiaoping in 1997 (who promoted the "Socialist Market" reforms), the 1996 Taiwan Strait Crisis, the 1999 U.S. bombing of the Chineseembassy in Serbia and the 2001 midair collision of a U.S. spy plane and Chinese ghter jet.3

average operating pro ts of 3 lp.We provide the theory in section 2; the data and empirical strategy in section 3; the estimates, robustness and preliminary quanti cation in 4; and conclude in section 5. Derivationand estimation details are in the appendices.2ModelWe consider a dynamic model of heterogeneous rms producing a di erentiated nal productfrom a primary factor (labor) and a continuum of intermediate inputs. Any rm present inthe market in period t survives into t 1 with probability , which is the only discount factorfor future pro ts. Firms enter and exit the market at a constant rate, such that their massis constant.In each period, the rm observes the prevailing input prices and makes three joint decisions: (a) how many varieties of each intermediate input to adopt; (b) how much to spendon each input, including labor; (c) the price of the nal good. To keep the last two decisionssimple, we assume functional forms such that expenditure shares and markups over marginalcost are constant.Inputs are indexed by i 2 [0; 1] and each i is available in a continuum of varieties on R .For each rm f and input i, we partition varieties into three disjoint intervals depending onwhether they require a sunk cost of adoption and are exposed to price risk. These intervalsare shown in Figure 2. The rst, [0; ni ], consists of safe varieties: those with no sunkcost and a xed price normalized to one. The second, ni ; ni if , consists of exposedvarieties: those with no sunk cost but a time-varying relative price, ti , which follows aMarkov process. The third, ni if ; 1 , consists of risky varieties: those with sunk costK 0 and the same time-varying relative price as exposed varieties. The last interval isour primary focus, as the combination of sunk cost and price risk distort the rm’s choice ofwhich (if any) varieties from this type to adopt.6 The parameter if governs the prevalenceof this distortion, which we allow to be both rm- and input-speci c. If if 0, all variableprice varieties are risky, whereas if if is large, risk becomes irrelevant.In light of our empirical application to a setting of trade policy uncertainty, we label[0; ni ] as domestic varieties and (ni ; 1) as imported varieties, of which ni if ; 1 arerisky. We interpret ti the tari -inclusive relative price of imported varieties. Our objectiveis to capture large permanent regime shifts in a tractable way. We follow Handley and Limão6There is a fourth possible con guration of sunk costs and price uncertainty, namely, those varieties witha xed price and K 0. We rule this case out, as it contributes very little to our analysis of imports underpolicy uncertainty.4

(2017) and model a three-state Markov process with an initial state tari vector l and aconstant probability that this policy changes the following period to a new vector s drawnwith probability s . We assume the following for tractability. First, there are only threestates with tari s ranked as follows h l g . Second, the extreme cases are absorbing(so there is only uncertainty in the initial intermediate state).To simplify the presentation we rst develop our results assuming g 0 so there aree ectively only two relevant cases and is the probability that the government increasesprotection. We then show that the results extend to allowing for a more favorable state, g 0, and is more easily interpreted as a measure of policy uncertainty. The equivalencebetween these two approaches is explained by the “bad news principle” (Bernanke, 1983):when rms can wait and see before making investments then only the expected severity ofbad news matters.2.1Preferences, Technology and Current Pro tsA rm is characterized by a productivity parameter 'f drawn from a common distributionand a set of parameters if drawn for each input independently from a common distributionG( ), both with non-negative support. For now we assume G( ) is absolutely continuousbut relax this subsequently. The parameters are drawn on entry and remain constant forthe life of the rm. In what follows, we consider the problem facing a generic rm and thusdrop the rm subscript for notational convenience.The rm faces a constant elasticity demand for its output given by,(1)q Epwhere p is the endogenous consumer price, E 0 is an exogenous demand shifter and 1the constant demand elasticity. This demand could be derived from a CES utility function,in which case E would contain the aggregate price index. Holding E constant, therefore,is equivalent to assuming that the nal goods market is large relative to the mass of rmsunder consideration.Production is Cobb-Douglas in labor and intermediate inputs, according to,ln y ln ' (1) ln l Z1ln (xi ) di(2)0where l is labor input and xi is the quantity of intermediate input i, and 1 is the costshare of intermediates. Each input is composed of a continuum of varieties aggregated with5

constant elasticity of substitution 1:xi Znixi ( )11(3)d0where ni is the measure of varieties (extensive margin) chosen.If the current relative price of imported varieties of input i is1a current cost index for input i of zi1 , wherezi (ni ; i ) (ni (nini )1inii,then a rm would haveif ni niif ni ni(4)Since the unit cost index is decreasing in zi the rm can lower it by expanding the extensivemargin. Therefore at the very least the rm adopts all varieties that carry no sunk adoptioncost, and hence we can con ne our attention to ni ni i .Aggregating over all inputs and normalizing w 1, the log unit cost of the nal good is,ln c ln ln ' 1Z1ln (zi ) diwhere (1) 1.The pro t-maximizing price of the nal good is p operating pro t of a rm can be written as,ln [ (z)] ln A (1) ln ' (5)0((1)11)Zc. Thus, the one-period log1ln (zi ) di(6)0where A E(1) 1 ( )1 .The partial derivative of the pro t function with respect to zi iszi (z)( (z)1) 1 01 zi(7)We show in the appendix that (z) is strictly concave if ( 11) 1. This is satis ed ifthe elasticity of substitution between two varieties of the same input is greater than thatbetween two di erent nal goods, i.e., , which we assume henceforth. Furthermore,di erentiation of (7) yields zi zj (z) 0 for all i 6 j, and thus (z) is supermodular.77By itself, Cobb-Douglas technology would imply that inputs are neither gross complements nor grosssubstitutes. Thus the supermodularity property, which gives rise to input complementarity in our model, isdriven by a pro t e ect alone. This is re‡ected in its dependence on the nal demand elasticity.6

2.2Input Choice under CertaintyBefore considering the problem with uncertainty, we solve the benchmark with certainty,i.e., 0, or equivalently, li hi i for all i. The rm chooses each ni to maximize theexpected present value of pro ts net of adoption costs,V (z) (z)1ZK1[ni(ni (8)i )] di0with ni ni i .The rst-order condition compares the marginal operating pro t from increasing zi withthe marginal cost of adding an imported variety with sunk cost K,zi (z)(1K)1(9)iwith strict equality for an interior solution, i.e., ni ni i .8Solving (9) for the optimal extensive margin of imports, nimax f i ; i g, where iinini , gives ni (10)( 1)and ini i 1 and. If the measure of exposed varieties i is su ciently( 1)(1 )Khigh, then the rm does not pay to adopt risky ones as well. Otherwise it does and in thatcase the extensive margin of imports is increasing in operating pro t, decreasing in owninput tari and on sunk cost.Using this we solve for import expenditure for each input. Given CES at the varietylevel, the share of imports in total spending on input i is,si nii ni(11)Domestic plus import expenditure on i is (1) , which follows from the Cobb-Douglasinput technology (see appendix). Thus import spending is,mi (1)ni;i niwhich increases with operating pro t and declines with own tari , viani , this expression becomes,8(12)i.Using the optimalWe abstract from sunk costs to start producing or importing. They are not necessary or su cient togenerate the impact of product speci c risk on imports that we subsequently nd. However, such costs could

Trade Symposium, International Trade Dynamics Workshop and NBER International Trade Policy and Institutions. Zhi Yu acknowledges support from the Public Computing Cloud Platform at Renmin University of China. The views

Related Documents:

TOFU BUY: 12- to 16-ounce container Brands and types shown here ONLY Not WIC Approved: With added fats, sugar, oil, or salt With added flavorings, sauces, or seasonings Azumaya Extra Firm Franklin Farms Firm, Medium Firm, Extra Firm, Soft House Foods Organic: Soft, Firm, Medium Firm, Extra Firm Premium: Soft, Firm, Medium Firm, Extra Firm

TFR "Best Law Firm in Trade Finance" Trade & Forfaiting Review (TFR) named Sullivan & Worcester "Best Law Firm in Trade Finance" in its 2014, 2015 and 2016 TFR Excellence Awards . GTR "Best Law Firm" Sullivan & Worcester UK LLP was top ranked firm in the . Global Trade Review (GTR) Best Law Firm 2015 and 2016 polls . The Legal 500 UK . 2016

external drain shield to the appropriate earth ground on one end. INPUT BOARD Input 3 Common Input 3 Input 4 Common Input 4 Input 1 Input 1 Common Input 2 Input 2 Common Relay 1 NO Relay 1 C Relay 1 NC Chassis GND At Other Panel 1 2 3 485-Com 485-Com - Com-Gnd RS 485 Com Bus Cable From Diff. Panel (Remote Mount Only) Power J1 - RS485 .

Running head: DOES CHOICE CAUSE AN ILLUSION OF CONTROL? 8 Koehler, Gibbs, & Hogarth, 1994; Langer, 1975; Nichols, Stich, Leslie, & Klein, 1996). In these studies, participants were randomly assigned to one of four conditions in a 2 x 2 design: Choice (Choice vs. No-choice) x Timing of Choice (Choice-first vs. Choice-last). Participants in the

500 100/120V ac 1746-IA16 Input 16 120V ac Input 15 101 200/240V ac 1746-IM4 Input 4 240V ac Input 15 301 200/240V ac 1746-IM8 Input 8 240V ac Input 15 501 200/240V ac 1746-IM16 Input 16 240V ac Input 15 2703 100/120V ac 1746-OA8 Output 8 120/240V ac Output 17

13.2 Trade costs and trade volumes in competitive, comparative-advantage models 13.3 Trade costs, prices discrimination, and trade volumes in oligopoly models 13.4 Trade costs, inter and intra-industry trade in monopolistic-competition models 13.5 The core-periphery model 13.6 Heterogeneous firms and firm-level export behavior 13.7 The gravity .

The impact of trade, page 2 INTRODUCTION Approximately 80 percent of global trade relies on some version of trade finance. The financing options may vary between open accounts, interfirm trade credit, or bank-intermediated trade finance (Chauffour and Malouche, 2011). During the latest financial recession, short-term trade finance fell .

of tank wall, which would be required by each design method for this example tank. The API 650 method is a working stress method, so the coefficient shown in the figure includes a factor of 2.0 for the purposes of comparing it with the NZSEE ultimate limit state approach. For this example, the 1986 NZSEE method gave a significantly larger impulsive mode seismic coefficient and wall thickness .