Knowledge Sources Of Entrepreneurship: Firm Formation By .

2y ago
32 Views
6 Downloads
1.38 MB
25 Pages
Last View : 1m ago
Last Download : 3m ago
Upload by : Adele Mcdaniel
Transcription

Research Policy 43 (2014) 1109–1133Contents lists available at ScienceDirectResearch Policyjournal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/respolKnowledge sources of entrepreneurship: Firm formation by academic,user and employee innovators夽Rajshree Agarwal a, , Sonali K. Shah babRobert H. Smith School of Business, University of Maryland, 4512 Van Munching Hall, College Park, MD 20742, United StatesFoster School of Business, University of Washington, Box 353200, Seattle, WA 98195, United Statesa r t i c l ei n f oArticle history:Received 31 March 2013Accepted 31 January 2014Available online 19 May 2014Keywords:Industry evolutionAcademic entrepreneurshipEmployee entrepreneurshipUser entrepreneurshipInnovationNew venture performancea b s t r a c tInnovative new ventures are at the heart of economic development, particularly when these startupsare created by employee, academic, and user innovators. We synthesize across literature streams examining each phenomena to document distinctions between firms originating from different “knowledgecontexts.” We then integrate the knowledge context into Teece’s (1986) theoretical framework identifying factors that impact a firm’s ability to profit from innovation. Doing so allows us to develop stylizedfacts and predictive propositions pertaining to differences in the innovative contributions, roles playedin shaping industrial dynamics and evolution, and performance outcomes for startups stemming fromthe three entrepreneurial origins. These propositions provide unique insights into the causes of patternsof industry evolution, contribute to theory in the areas of entrepreneurship and industry evolution, andyield important policy and managerial implications. 2014 Published by Elsevier B.V.1. IntroductionAcross economics, sociology, psychology, policy, and management, differential knowledge resources has been identified as acentral factor that gives rise to and shapes innovative new ventures.This focus dates back to Schumpeter (1934) and Hayek (1945), whosuggested that information asymmetries arising from differencesin knowledge are at the heart of why some individuals identifyand exploit entrepreneurial opportunities before others (Kirzner,1997). “Knowledge corridors” allow some aspiring entrepreneursto create innovations, as well as to amass the necessary resourcesand complementary assets required to transform innovative ideasinto viable commercial products and services through the formation of firms (Venkataraman, 1997).Consistent with this notion, significant scholarly attentionhas recently been devoted to understanding three sources ofinnovative new ventures: employee entrepreneurship, academic夽 Both authors contributed equally and the author sequence is alphabetical. We aregrateful for support from the Ewing Marion Kauffman Foundation. The manuscripthas benefited from comments received from the editor, two anonymous reviewers,Seth Carnahan, Emily Cox, Justin Frake, Martin Ganco, Daniel Olson, Margaret O’Maraand presentations at University of Maryland and 2013 Academy of ManagementMeetings. The usual disclaimer applies. Corresponding author.E-mail addresses: rajshree@umd.edu (R. Agarwal), skshah@u.washington.edu(S.K. 120048-7333/ 2014 Published by Elsevier B.V.entrepreneurship, and user entrepreneurship. Each of these bodiesof work has developed independently, but they share a commonunderpinning: each focuses on a “knowledge context” in whichan individual develops informational advantages that serve as thebasis for the creation of a new firm. Production in existing firms isthe knowledge context for employee entrepreneurship, where individuals employed by existing organizations in the focal industryventure out to capitalize on knowledge gained through employment (Agarwal et al., 2004; Klepper, 2001; Phillips, 2002). Researchin academic institutions serves as the knowledge context for academic entrepreneurship, when firms are founded by scientists whoinnovate in the context of universities, national labs, or institutions that undertake basic research (Audretsch and Feldman, 1996;Feldman et al., 2005; Lockett et al., 2005; Mowery, 2005; Zuckeret al., 1998). Finally, user entrepreneurship is the founding of firmsby individuals who innovate in the knowledge context of using thefocal product or service (Baldwin et al., 2006; Shah, 2005; Shahand Tripsas, 2007). These three knowledge contexts reflect theinstitutional backdrops that appear to seed the majority of innovations. Taken together, these three contexts span the focal industryand also upstream “science push” and downstream “demand pull”knowledge sources (Dosi, 1988; Nelson, 1959; Scherer, 1982).Comparing and contrasting new ventures originating from different contexts permits us to expose the systematic differencesbetween these firms along numerous strategic dimensions, therebyillustrating that the knowledge context from which a firm originates does indeed matter. Our objectives in this paper are two-fold.

1110R. Agarwal, S.K. Shah / Research Policy 43 (2014) 1109–1133First, we provide a review and synthesis of extant literature onemployee, academic, and user entrepreneurship to identify systematic patterns pertaining to the characteristics of the innovativeknowledge exploited, access to complementary assets, intellectual property protection, entry timing, performance outcomes;and relationships with established firms. Second, we integrate theknowledge context into Teece’s (1986) framework for profitingfrom innovation. We build and present theoretical arguments thatserve to explain and extend empirically observed patterns, as wellas highlight the differential contributions of firms from each of thethree knowledge contexts to innovation and to industrial development and evolution.Our primary contributions are to the innovation and industry evolution literatures. By adding the knowledge context as afourth factor in the Teece framework, we deepen predictive insightsregarding which firms will profit from innovation and the factorsthat will enable them to do so. Our refinement of Teece’s frameworkalso theorizes that the strength and importance of appropriability regimes increase as industries evolve, by drawing on empiricalsupport from existing studies. By combining the novel insightsthat (a) the knowledge context shapes an innovative new venture’s capabilities and (b) appropriability regimes tend to increasein strength over the industry life cycle with established wisdomthat the importance of complementary assets increases over theindustry life cycle, we provide explanations for several patterns inindustry evolution.We also contribute to the entrepreneurship literature throughthe systematic comparison of new ventures originating acrossthe three distinct knowledge contexts. Entrepreneurial innovationoccurs when startup firms introduce innovations into the commercial marketplace, becoming important sources of technological andindustrial progress (Baumol, 2002; Scherer, 1980). We focus on a“first principles” approach to entrepreneurial innovation: we highlight the underlying seedbeds—i.e. the knowledge contexts—fromwhich innovative new ventures arise, distinguish among the contributions of each type of innovative new venture, and identify themanner in which various factors differentially shape each type ofentrepreneurial entry and their post entry activities. By integrating insights across literature streams that have largely developedin isolation to each other, our theoretical framework provides aparsimonious rationale for how the knowledge context shapes formation and modes of value capture by new ventures, and howand when each type of entrepreneurial venture is likely to contribute to an industry’s growth and evolution. In doing so, weshow how heterogeneity in entrepreneurial innovations arise andprovide policy-makers, practitioners, and investors with a nuancedbasis from which to make decisions regarding how to promoteentrepreneurial innovation.2. The knowledge context and entrepreneurshipScholarship in entrepreneurship, innovation and strategy hasmade significant strides recently in examining how the macroknowledge context relates to the micro-underpinnings of newfirm formation and performance. Since start-ups benefit from thepre-entry experience and knowledge embodied in their founders,independent literature streams have examined how individualsgain knowledge related to the production and marketing ofthe focal products and services (employee entrepreneurship),in the process of scientific discovery in academic institutions(academic entrepreneurship), and in the use of these products and services (user entrepreneurship). We synthesize acrossthese literature streams by formally defining them, discussingthe industries and sampling frames used as an empirical context, and reporting on the known prevalence of each type ofentrepreneurship. We then document patterns along the following dimensions: the type of knowledge and innovation exploitedthrough firm formation; the relevance of the three factors highlighted by Teece (1986)—complementary assets, appropriabilityregimes and industry life cycle1 ; new ventures’ relationshipwith established firms; and finally, their performance subsequentto entry.We impose the following boundary conditions on our review.First, we note that the three knowledge contexts are neither mutually exclusive nor exhaustive. For example, industrial scientistsmay work on basic research in corporate labs, such as Xerox PARCor Bell Labs, where industry and academic science norms comingle (Chesbrough and Rosenbloom, 2002; Holbrook et al., 2000).Also, individual entrepreneurs may possess varied career historiesthat provide them with knowledge from multiple contexts (Moseyand Wright, 2007; Wennberg et al., 2011). For example, employees of firms may be user innovators, resulting in a hybrid of userand employee entrepreneurship (Fontana and Malerba, 2010; Shahet al., 2012). Further, firms may be formed by entrepreneurial teamscomposed of members from various knowledge contexts: whetherthis leads to “super” firms endowed with a great array of knowledgeand/or firms plagued by conflict is an empirical question that hasyet to be investigated.2 For simplicity, we limit our examination tothe three “pure” entrepreneurial contexts, but note exceptions asthey arise. Also, while not exhaustive, the three knowledge contexts span the focal industry, as well as upstream “science push”and downstream “demand pull” knowledge sources (Dosi, 1988;Nelson, 1959; Scherer, 1982). That said, other important knowledge contexts include industries that are otherwise related to thefocal industry context, including complementary or supplier products and services. We do not discuss these contexts, given lack ofsystematic literature streams on these origins.Second, we limit attention to entrepreneurial firm formation, andnot the broader literature on academic, employee and user innovation. We assume that the innovation being commercialized hasalready been developed, and focus on situations where the calculusacross alternative options (licensing technology, free dissemination, etc.) has resulted in firm formation, to provide products orservices for the end consumer or other firms in the ecosystem.Finally, we employ an inductive approach, focusing on identifying empirical patterns prior to creating a theoretical framework.According, our review focuses only on papers that have an empiricalcontext and findings.31Teece’s (1986) framework identified complementary assets, appropriabilityregimes, and industry life cycle stages as critical factors that influence a firm’s ability to profit from innovation. Complementary assets required for the development,manufacture or distribution of an innovative product or service may consist of physical capital, brand equity, organizational knowledge, and tacit human capital of otheremployees. Appropriability regimes are “environmental factors, excluding firm andmarket structure, that govern an innovator’s ability to capture the profits generatedby an innovation,” which depend on the technology and the efficacy of propertyrights protection offered through legal mechanisms. Finally, while Teece distinguished between pre and post dominant design based on Abernathy and Utterback’s(1978), scholars have differentiated between early, growth and mature periods ofthe industry life cycle due to transformations in the underlying market structure(Agarwal et al., 2002; Gort and Klepper, 1982).2For example, Franklin et al. (2001) show that when university policies permituse of “surrogate” entrepreneurs in launching academic founded firms, there aremore venture launches.3We used the following process to identify relevant work: First, we selectedleading papers based on citations in Google Scholar. Our search terms includedthe breadth represented in each stream (e.g. in employee entrepreneurship, wesearched on this term, and terms such as spinouts, spawns, and intra-industryspinoffs). We then conducted forward and backward citation searches, and appendedto the literature review based on our own expertise and knowledge of relevantwork. While we do not claim to have reviewed every paper in each literature stream,our methodology captures the most cited research, and works they draw upon andgenerate.

R. Agarwal, S.K. Shah / Research Policy 43 (2014) 1109–11332.1. Employee entrepreneurship2.1.1. Empirical context and sampling frame used in studiesEmployee entrepreneurship is defined as new venture creationwhen employees of existing firms found a firm in the same industry (Agarwal et al., 2004; Klepper, 2002). Dominant labels of thesenew ventures include “intra-industry spin-offs” (Klepper, 2002), or“spin-outs” (Agarwal et al., 2004), and the attention is focused oncontexts where both the “parent” firm and the spawn operate in thesame industry. Table 1 summarizes across the key empirical studieson employee entrepreneurship. The studies cover both professionalservices and high-technology manufacturing, and represent longhistories, some dating back into the nineteenth century. Garvin(1983), seemingly first to document the phenomena, compiledimpressive anecdotal evidence spanning several industries. Brittainand Freeman (1986) and Mitton (1990) followed, with a researchdesign that now characteristics scholarly work that has explodedin the area: comprehensive and longitudinal single industry studies that track genealogical relationships between firms due to theemployee-founders. The benefits of employing such a samplingframe include the ability to measure the incidence of employeeentrepreneurship and track their relative performance. A cost of thesampling frame, however, is that single industry context studies donot facilitate inter-industry comparisons of factors that impact theformation and performance of the new ventures. Further, the generalizability of the studies are limited to a synthesis of the results,an issue we attempt to address in this study, rather than a formaland empirical examination of the boundary conditions under whichthe phenomena is prevalent.2.1.2. Type of knowledge or innovation utilized in firm formationTheir knowledge context provides the founders with criticaltechnology, operations and market knowledge. Technical knowledge capitalized by employee founded firms includes codifiedinformation in the form of products, patents, or firm routines.Agarwal et al. (2004) provide quantitative evidence regarding theinheritance of technological capabilities in the disk drive industry,and Klepper and Sleeper (2005) document the leveraging of parent firm technology (patents and products) in the laser industry.Tacit technical know-how is also identified as a critical resource(Clarysse et al., 2011c), whether in high technology contexts suchas automobiles, biotechnology, and semiconductors, or in knowledge intensive service industries, such as fashion design and legalservices. Often, as in medical devices (Chatterji, 2009), the tacitknowledge may include operational knowledge for navigating regulatory processes and clinical trials.Market and business knowledge are also exploited by employeefounded firms. Moore and Davis (2004) note that the managerialskills learned by technical personnel employed at Fairchild Semiconductor was critical in their subsequent decisions to venture outand found firms that contributed to the vibrancy of Silicon Valley.Agarwal et al. (2004) and Franco and Filson (2006) systematicallylink employee founded firms’ ability to pioneer new product markets within the disk drive industries to their parent’s market pioneering capabilities. These “entrepreneurial capabilities” are alsohighlighted by Ellis et al. (2008) in the information technology andcommunications industry. Importantly, in knowledge intensiveservice industries, industry specific knowledge residing in humancapital is of critical importance, as documented by studies of thelegal services (Campbell et al., 2012; Carnahan et al., 2012; Phillips,2002) and winery industries (Simons and Roberts, 2008). In part,this is also due to access to important resources through social networks (Sorenson and Audia, 2000; Stuart and Sorenson, 2003a,b).As seen in Table 1, almost all studies note the prevalence ofboth product and process innovation. This is understandable, sinceemployee-founders are armed not only with technical and market1111know-how that enable product innovation, but also operationalknowledge in the focal industry context, which enables processinnovations targeted toward efficiencies in production.2.1.3. Dimensions of the Teece framework—complementaryassets, appropriability regimes and the industry life cycleVarious complementary assets have been identified in the studies of employee entrepreneurship. Table 1 shows that employeefounded firms leverage physical and organizational knowledge (e.g.routines) as complementary capabilities (Brittain and Freeman,1986; Ganco, 2013; Garvin, 1983; Klepper, 2002; Klepper andSleeper, 2005). Further, Klepper and Sleeper (2005) note thatknowledge becomes increasingly embedded in physical ratherthan human capital in the laser industry context over time. Otherstudies highlight the ability of employee founded firms to accessboth upstream scientific knowledge and downstream distributionand market channels (Chatterji, 2009; Mitton, 1990; Stuart andSorenson, 2003a,b). In knowledge intensive professional serviceindustries, employee founded firms benefit from the ability totransfer and recreate complementary human capital and organizational routines (Campbell et al., 2012; Carnahan et al., 2012;Dahl and Reichstein, 2007; Wennberg, 2009). Still others highlightcomplementary assets that stem from geographical proximity:Sorenson and Audia (2000) document high and stable geographical clustering in the US footwear industry that relate to supply ofresources, and Klepper (2002) and Buenstorf and Klepper (2009)also highlight location preferences of employee entrepreneursin the automobile and tires industries. Geographical proximityprovides social networks and access to venture financing, two complementary assets emphasized in studies related to biotechnologyand semiconductors (Mitton, 1990; Moore and Davis, 2004; Stuartand Sorenson, 2003a,b).Employee founded firms are prevalent regardless of whetherindustries are characterized by strong or weak appropriability regimes. Employee entrepreneurship has been documentedin several industry contexts—medical, biotechnology and semiconductors in particular—with strong appropriability regimes builton patents and trade secrets (Chatterji, 2009; Ganco, 2013; Stuartand Sorenson, 2003a,b). Strong appropriability regimes seem toboth foster and deter employee entrepreneurship. On the one hand,studies have highlighted high rates of employee entrepreneurshipby founders possessing intellectual property rights in the form ofpatents (Ganco, 2013; Hall and Ziedonis, 2001; Kim and Marschke,2005; Klepper and Sleeper, 2005). On the other hand, scholars havealso noted the strategic use of patent thickets by established firmsto stave competition (Ziedonis, 2004), and aggressive IP litigationto reduce knowledge spillovers through employee mobility andentrepreneurship (Agarwal et al., 2009; Ganco et al., 2013; Klepperand Sleeper, 2005). A number of studies of employee entrepreneurship have also been conducted in weak appropriability regimes,including consulting, legal services, fashion design, and wineries(Campbell et al., 2012; Carnahan et al., 2012; Garvin, 1983; Phillips,2002; Simons and Roberts, 2008; Wenting, 2008). Almost all ofthese studies document knowledge transfers and spillovers to thenew ventures (Agarwal et al., 2013; Campbell et al., 2012). Forexample, studies of legal services, a context notorious for weakappropriability since even non-compete contracts are not applicable, document both high rates of employee entrepreneurshipand adverse effects on parent performance (Campbell et al., 2012;Phillips, 2002). Other studies, on wineries, for instance, documenttransfer of tacit local and non-local knowledge across organizations through employee entrepreneurship (Simons and Roberts,2008). Thus, in weak appropriability regimes, employee foundedfirms seem to suffer less from a deterrent effect, and capitalize ontacit knowledge and industry specific information gained throughemployment.

1112Table 1Empirical studies on employee entrepreneurship.StudyTime periodcoveredSamplingframeType ofknowledgeType rsAutomobilesGarvin (1983)Histories ofvariousindustriesAnecdotalProduct andprocessPhysical capitalNAKlepper calknowledgeProduct andprocessPhysical sStrongBiotechnologyMitton (1990)and Stuart udinalhistoryTechnologicalknowledgeNAStrongDisk drivesAgarwal et al.(2004),Christensen(1997), Francoand Filson(2006) andMcKendricket al. echnologicalknowledge,marketknowledgeProduct andprocessUpstreamaccess toscientificknowledge anddownstreamaccess tomarketsPhysical capitalandorganizationalknowledgeFashion Product andprocessFootwearSorenson andAudia chnology andcommunicationEllis et ryLasersKlepper andSleeper (2005)and eTechnologicalknowledge,marketknowledgeStage ofindustry lifecycleGrowth andlate stages;successfulemployeefounded firmsenter earlierGrowth andlate stagesPercentage ofemployeefounded denovo entrantsRelationshipwithEstablishedFirms atFoundingPerformanceNACompetition inearly stages;cooperation inlate stagesCompetition(foundings dueto strategicdisagreements)Not studied24%Employeefounded firmsoutperform allentrants in termsof survival45%Competition(lower IPOprobability inmoreconcentratedregions)Not studiedCompetition(mostemployeefounded firmsentered insamegeneration asparent firm) orno overlapCompetitionEmployeefounded firmsoutperform allentrants in termsof survivalStrongGrowth andlate stages;significantfraction of earlymovers in newgenerations areemployeefounded firms25%NAWeakGrowth andmature stages42%Product andprocessLocation andagglomerationeffectsNANot discussedProduct andprocessNANAGrowth andlate stagesNA (states withhigher densityof incumbentshave higherfirm formationrates)82%ProductOver time,knowledgeincreasinglyembedded inphysical ratherthan humancapitalStrongincreasing andthendecreasingover time41% employeefounded; 23%academicfounded(footnote 11)CompetitionCompetitionLargely,competition,but fewinstances ofcollaborationor low overlapEmployeefounded firmsoutperform allentrants in termsof survivalGrowth andsurvivalnegativelyrelated togeographicalconcentrationNot studiedEmployeefounded firms,particularly ed allother entrantsR. Agarwal, S.K. Shah / Research Policy 43 (2014) 1109–1133Industry

Phillips (2002),Campbell et al.(2012) andCarnahan et ionaland otherhuman assetsWeakNA27%Competition(employeefounded firmshave a negativeeffect on parentperformance)Medical ��nancingStrongNA36%; 29% areacademic orusersNo overlapSemiconductorsBrittain andFreeman(1986), Fontanaand Malerba(2010), Ganco(2013) andMoore andDavis (2004)Buenstorf andKlepper echnologicalandoperationalknowledgeProduct andprocessPhysical capitalandorganizationalknowledgeStrongGrowth andlate stages41%Competition(frustrationidentified as afrequent causefor istoryNALocation andagglomerationeffectsNAGrowth andlate stages85%CompetitionNot studiedWineriesSimons andRoberts ledgeProduct andprocessNAWeakHigher entryrates in growthperiod nsiveservices and hightechmanufacturing)Wennberget al. echnologicalknowledgeNotdiscussedNot discussedStrong andweakNA94%Competition(employeefounded firmsentered insame marketsegment asparents)NAPre-foundingexperience haspositive effectson both size oforganization andquality ofproductHigher growthand likelihood ofsurvival relativeto academicentrepreneurshipTiresR. Agarwal, S.K. Shah / Research Policy 43 (2014) 1109–1133Employeefounded firmswith higherquality founders(experience,rank, earnings)are associatedwith highersurvivalEmployeefounded firmsperform betterthan otherentrants in termsof venturefinancing andvaluationEmployeefounded firmsperform betterthan otherentrantsLegal services1113

1114R. Agarwal, S.K. Shah / Research Policy 43 (2014) 1109–1133The sampling frame used in employee entrepreneurship studies is particularly amenable to studying the effect of industryevolution on new firm formation. Almost all studies reported inTable 1 find employee founded firms to be most prevalent in thegrowth and mature stages. In part, this may be tautological—asthe number of firms in the industry increases, so does the population of employees that are at risk of spinning out. However, theincidence of employee entrepreneurship is not a mere mathematical artifact. Increases in industry specific knowledge, and shiftingfocus on operational knowledge and process innovation over time(Abernathy and Utterback, 1978; Gort and Klepper, 1982) wouldfoster higher rates of employee entrepreneurship in the growthand mature stages of the industries. In addition, it is not the number of potential parent firms per se, but the quality of those firmsthat determines the propensity of employees to found firms: evidence from automobiles, disk drives, lasers, semiconductors andtires, show that abundant under-utilized knowledge among highperforming firms results in greater rates of employee entrepreneurship (Agarwal et al., 2004; Buenstorf and Klepper, 2009; Klepper,2002; Moore and Davis, 2004).2.1.4. Firm formation and relationship with established firms inthe industryStudies of employee entrepreneurship find that the fraction ofemployee founded firms in an industry range from approximately25% of start-up activity in industries such as automobiles and diskdrives (Agarwal et al., 2004; Klepper, 2002) to a staggering 80%and above in industries such as information technology and communications, and tires (Buenstorf and Klepper, 2009; Ellis et al.,2008).4Employee founded firms often compete with and sometimescomplement, but rarely cooperate with established firms; this distinction may be based on the motives of employee entrepreneurs.Most studies reviewed in Table 1 document a competitive relationship with the established parent. Regardless of whether employeedepartures are motivated by strategic disagreements (Klepper,2002, 2007), underexploited knowledge (Agarwal et al., 2004),or learning through apprenticeship (Franco and Filson, 2006),employee founded firms imitate core capabilities and strategiesfrom their parents and compete in the same industry segmentsand submarkets. As a result, studies consistently find that employeeentrepreneurship negatively impacts parent performance, perhapseven resulting in parent firm exit (Campbell et al., 2012; Francoand Filson, 2006; McKendrick et al., 2009; Moore and Davis, 2004;Phillips, 2002).When under-utilized knowledge is the impetus, employeefounded firms are more likely to enter niche or new market segments, or build on technological advances left unexploited by theparent firm (Agarwal et al., 2004; Klepper and Sleeper, 2005). Insome instances, the new market segments transitioned from lowmarket overlap to greater competition (Christensen, 1997; Francoand Filson, 2006); while in others, the firms co-existed in nonoverlapping market segments for the entire observed time period(Klepper and Sleeper, 2005).Instances of collaboration between employee founded firmsand established firms are not often observed, although a fewexceptions—often involving technology licensing and venturefinancing—have been documented (Garvin, 1983; Klepper andSleeper, 2005). Agarwal et al. (2007) provide anecdotal evidenceregarding the process of creative construction, whereby employeefounded and parent firms occupy complementary or vertical4The statistics are computed with the denominator being all new ventures (butnot all entrants) in the industry, and thus excludes diversifying firms (existing firmsin other ind

R. Agarwal, S.K. Shah / Research Policy 43 (2014) 1109–1133 1111 2.1. Employee entrepreneurship 2.1.1. Empirical context and sampling frame used in studies Employee entrepreneurship is defined as new venture creation when employees of existing firms found a firm in the same indus-try (Agarwal

Related Documents:

TOFU BUY: 12- to 16-ounce container Brands and types shown here ONLY Not WIC Approved: With added fats, sugar, oil, or salt With added flavorings, sauces, or seasonings Azumaya Extra Firm Franklin Farms Firm, Medium Firm, Extra Firm, Soft House Foods Organic: Soft, Firm, Medium Firm, Extra Firm Premium: Soft, Firm, Medium Firm, Extra Firm

To define the entrepreneurship. To explain the significance of Entrepreneurship. To explain the Entrepreneurship Development. To describe the Dynamics of Entrepreneurship Development. 1.1 Need and significance of Entrepreneurship Development in Global contexts It is said that an economy is an effect for which entrepreneurship is the cause.

CHAPTER 2: ENTREPRENEURSHIP THEORY AND CREATIVITY ctives. epreneurs. reneurship. 3:49). thought on the meaning of entrepreneurship. One group focused on the characteris-tics of entrepreneurship (e.g. innovation, growth, uniqueness) while a second group focused on the outcomes of entrepreneurship (e.g. the creation of value).

identify and describe characterizations of technology entrepreneurship, digital techno-logy entrepreneurship, and digital entrepreneurship. With this new delineation of terms, we would like to foster discussion between researchers, entrepreneurs, and policy makers on the impact of digitization on entrepreneurship, and set a future research agenda.

Digital entrepreneurship is the phenomenon associated with digital entrepreneurial activity. While the expressions ‘ICT entrepreneurship’ and ‘digital entrepreneurship’ are widely used, we have opted to use only the expression ‘digital entrepreneurship’ in this

Academic entrepreneurship: time for a rethink? 9 As academic entrepreneurship has evolved, so too must scholarly analysis of academic entrepreneurship. There has been a rise in scholarly interest in academic entrepreneurship in the social sciences (e.g., economics, sociology, psychology, and political science) and several fields of business

Global Entrepreneurship Education II- FRAMEWORK TABLE 1: CASES BY LEARNER CATEGORY III- ENTREPRENEURSHIP EDUCATION IN CHINA The Maker Space of Tsinghua University High School: Extreme Learning Process (XLP) For Entrepreneurship Education Tsinghua x-lab: a University-based Platform For Creativity, Innovation and Entrepreneurship Education

The Group met four times in Brussels to complete its work: on 12 December 2013, on 14/15 January 2014, on 13/14 March 2014 and on 24/25 April 2014. During the term of the Group Mr Pierre Collin was appointed as member of the cabinet of Mr Moscovici, Minister of Finance in France. He continued participating in