Uncertain Economic Growth And Sprawl: Evidence From A .

3y ago
31 Views
2 Downloads
514.39 KB
43 Pages
Last View : 23d ago
Last Download : 3m ago
Upload by : Duke Fulford
Transcription

Uncertain Economic Growth and Sprawl:Evidence from a Stochastic Growth Approach*Belal Fallah1Mark Partridge2Rose Olfert3June 26, 2011Acknowledgement: We thank Infrastructure Canada for their support in funding part of thisresearch under a grant titled. "Mapping the Rural-Urban Interface: Partnerships for SustainableInfrastructure Development." We also thank the Canada Rural Revitalization Foundation and theFederation of Canadian Municipalities for their support of this project, in particular RobertGreenwood. An earlier version of this paper was presented at the Canadian AgricultureEconomics Society Meeting. We thank Elena Irwin for her helpful comments and suggestions.1College of Administrative Sciences and Informatics, Palestine Polytechnic University.bfallah2000@yahoo.com.2Swank Professor of Rural-Urban Policy and Professor, Department of Agricultural, Environmental, andDevelopment Economics, Ohio State University. Partridge.27@osu.edu (contact).3Johnson-Shoyama Graduate School of Public Policy, University of Saskatchewan. rose.olfert@usask.ca* The final publication is available at springerlink.com

1Uncertain Economic Growth and Sprawl: Evidence from a Stochastic Growth ApproachAbstract: This paper examines how the volatility of local economies, represented by uncertaintyover future land rents, affects urban sprawl. We develop a theoretical model that links sprawl toshocks to expected rent from future land development, among other factors. The econometricanalysis draws upon panel data from U.S. metropolitan areas. To measure urban sprawl, weconstruct a distinctive measure that captures the distribution of population density withinmetropolitan areas. Using a proxy for uncertainty over future land rents, we confirm thetheoretical prediction that across U.S. metropolitan areas, higher levels of uncertainty areassociated with lower levels of sprawl.Keywords: Economic Growth; Sprawl1. IntroductionThe emergence of urban sprawl in North America in the mid-20th Century has spawned aliterature investigating its forms and effects, as well as aimed at understanding its underlyingcauses. Understanding the causes of urban sprawl is important because it represents an importantshift in population distribution and land-use as it reshapes the rural-urban interface, pushingdevelopment well out into what were historically rural communities, changing the distribution ofeconomic activities across urban areas. These in turn potentially affect productivity (Fallah et al.,forthcoming) and potentially foster environmental degradation (Carruthers and Vias 2005;Glaeser and Kahn 2004). Sprawl can also affect the quality of life through impacts on the cost ofinfrastructure provision and the work-commute relationship (Carruthers and Ulfarsson 2008; Wu2010). Because attempts to mitigate greenhouse gas emissions will likely entail more planningand zoning to reduce energy usage, the need to understand the causes of sprawl will likelyintensify.Urban economists have traditionally used the theory of the static monocentric city to explain theforces underlying urban sprawl and the implied decrease in population density farther from thecentral business district (CBD). In the absence of a single precise definition of urban sprawl, weuse the term objectively to mean low density development with the expansion of urbandevelopment into (previously) undeveloped rural areas and interior urban areas (e.g., Nechybaand Walsh, 2004). Thus, we assess the key feature of most discussion of sprawl, namely the

2relatively low land-use intensity of development, leaving the impacts on efficiency to furtherempirical investigation.The expansion of the urban structure hinges on the tradeoff between land rent and commutingcosts. In equilibrium, this requires lower land rent at the urban fringe to offset the highercommuting cost to the CBD. The declining rent gradient leads to a decline in the density gradient(often modeled as a constant decline) as distance increases from CBD to the urban fringe (Alonso1964; Muth 1969; Mills 1967). Research on sprawl has typically used this model as a startingpoint to propose a variety of causes of sprawl. 1Despite its success in reproducing general aspects of the urban spatial structure, the staticmonocentric model has been criticized by many urban economists. For example, Anas (1978)suggests that the monotonic decline of density away from the CBD occurs only under specialconditions, such as rising income levels. Moreover, in dynamic models with durable housing andmyopic landowners, Anas (1978), Harrison and Kain (1974), and McFarlane (1999) argue thatresidential development around the employment center is an incremental process and that densitydepends on the economic conditions at the time of development.Dynamic models have conventionally assumed that a risk-neutral developer will choose to investwhen the present value of expected cash flows exceeds the cost of development. However, if thefuture cash flow is uncertain and the investment is durable and irreversible, as in landdevelopment, this principle must be modified. For example, as in our model, consider an openurban area experiencing shocks in labor demand.2 The resulting shocks in population growth andhousing demand lead to an uncertain future land/housing rent to be earned from developing newlots. Titman (1985), McDonald and Siegel (1985, 1986), and others suggest that under1For example, past research has proposed many causes of sprawl such as rising income (Margo 1992),declining transportation costs (Glaeser and Kahn 2004), fragmented local governance (Carruthers 2003),and improved infrastructure such as improved highways (Baum-Snow 2007).2The shock could be to households—changes in labor supply—perhaps due to amenities. However, it ismore likely due to be a labor demand shock.

3uncertainty and illiquid durable investment, developers may choose to delay investment. Theability to delay investment decisions has economic value, i.e., a real option (Pindyck 1991).Cappoza and Helsley (1990) were among the first to explore the relationship between urbanspatial structure and uncertainty. Assuming that future rent follows a stochastic pattern, theyfound that in cities with a higher level of uncertainty, developers would delay land developmentuntil the expected future rent (usually referred to as reservation or hurdle rent) compensates notonly for the agricultural land value and conversion cost, as in the case of a certain future, but alsofor the real option value. In their model, the real option value reflects the ability to delay landdevelopment while awaiting more information on future land prices. As a result of thedevelopment delay, Cappoza and Helsley (1990) suggest that the expected city size decreases, allelse constant.3In examining the effect of uncertainty on city size, Capozza and Helsley (1990) assume that thelot size is fixed across urban areas. Capozza and Li (1994) extend this work by investigating theinteraction between uncertainty and the ability to vary residential capital intensity. Assuming thatdevelopers choose the optimum capital intensity and time of development, they find thatuncertainty raises the reservation rent and delays the development decision.To date, urban economists have done little to empirically test the implications of models thatrelate uncertainty about future land rent to urban spatial structure. 4 The objective of this paper isto address this gap. Specifically, we investigate how variations in uncertainty over future rentexplain differences in the extent of U.S. metropolitan sprawl. The importance of this questderives from policymakers' and urban planners' need to understand how an expanding and volatile3Bar-Ilan and Strange (1996) extend the Capozza and Helsley (1990) model to allow for lags between thedecision to develop a project and its completion. In this scenario, development lags may lead to a leap frogpattern where more distant land is developed prior to that closer to the city center. Mills (1981) alsomodeled scenarios in which a leap frog development pattern occurs under uncertainty and perfect foresightassumption.4Most of the related literature on uncertainty (real options) has focused on capital investment (e.g,Caballero and Pindyck 1996; Paddock et al. 1988; Moel and Tufano 2002). Fewer studies have exploredlinkages between uncertainty and real estate. For example, Holland et al. (2000) examined the effect ofprice uncertainty on changes in property size.

4urban economy can influence urban sprawl so that they can better address its impacts on thelivability of the urban environment, residence-work commute relationships, and the provision ofphysical infrastructure (roads, schools, sewers, and other public facilities).We depart from the work of Capozza and Helsley (1990) and Capozza and Li (1994) as follows:Capozza and Li‘s (1994) model is site-specific, predicting the irregular intra-metropolitan densityprofile rather than the overall density distribution. The latter is the emphasis of this paper. Inaddition, Capozza and Helsley (1990), focusing on the relationship between uncertainty andurban size, assume that each household consumes one unit of a fixed-sized lot, leading to constantdensity across urban areas. We relax the fixed-size assumption by allowing householdpreferences to determine lot size. Note that 'the lot' remains the unit of new land developmentwith implications for how uncertainty in population growth is represented, namely in terms ofabsolute growth and how much land is developed.In this paper, we also seek a theoretically consistent measure of sprawl that links metropolitanpopulation density to uncertainty, differing from previous work in two ways. First, our modeldoes not include structural capital. Instead, the variation in the density (sprawl) across urban areasarises from variations in lot size. Second, unlike Capozza and Li (1994), we assume that therepresentative household chooses the optimal lot size through utility maximization behavior (seeWu 2010), while a representative developer takes the optimal lot size as given and chooses theoptimal time to convert agricultural land into residential use. In practice, this is akin to assumingthe construction industry is relatively competitive, allowing household preferences to determinelot size (perhaps through the political process and zoning), which is more realistic than a fixed lotsize across the entire urban area. To account for varying density across an urban area, we assumethere is a composition effect where new lot development in the interior of the city is denser thandevelopment at the urban periphery, while the elasticity of lot size also plays a differential rolebetween the periphery and interior.

5Assuming that the future rent of developed land evolves in a stochastic fashion and solving foroptimal lot size and optimal conversion time, we derive an expression that links populationdensity to a reservation land rent. As in Capozza and Helsley (1990), the reservation rent is afunction of shocks to expected future developed-land rent (among other factors), reflecting thereal option value. A higher level of uncertainty raises the reservation rent in order to cover thereal option value of delaying development.Our econometric analysis uses panel data from U.S. metropolitan areas over the 1980-2000period. Consistent with the theoretical model, we construct a distinct sprawl measure thatcaptures both overall density and population distribution. The sprawl index measures the share ofthe population that lives in low density block groups within a metropolitan area (MA). The paneldata allows us to capture unmeasured aspects of each MA. Then using variations in populationchange as a proxy for how labor demand shocks affect future land rent, we provide robustevidence that greater uncertainty is negatively related to urban sprawl.The only empirical study that has tackled the issue of uncertainty and sprawl, that we are awareof, is Burchfield et al. (2006). Unlike our approach, their sprawl definition is specific to leap frogtype sprawl, measured as the amount of undeveloped land surrounding an average urbandwelling. Their measure of sprawl is different from ours in that we use a population density basedmeasure of sprawl. They find that uncertainty is positively associated with delaying thedevelopment decision. 5In what follows, Section 2 presents the theoretical model. Section 3 describes the sprawl measure,followed by the empirical model and empirical results in section 4. Section 5 presents sensitivityanalysis. Finally, section 6 concludes with some policy implications.5A related study is Cunningham‘s (2006) assessment of how real-option behavior influences vacant landprices. His findings are consistent with real option theory—a higher level of uncertainty delaysdevelopment and increases land prices.

62. Theoretical model2.1 Household ProblemOur theoretical model is consistent with an open city model, where economic activities areconcentrated in its central business district (CBD), a point to which households commute daily.Residential locations are indexed by their distance, z, from the CBD. The cost of commuting isnormalized to 1 per kilometer. Households are identical in terms of tastes and income, y, whichis assumed, for now, to be exogenous to the size of the city population. Households in each periodderive their utility, u(m,q), from consuming land (lot) denoted by q, and numéraire non-landgoods, denoted by m. The price of m is normalized to 1. The budget constraint of households isgiven by: m Rq y - z, where R is land rent.The (residential) mobility of urban households across urban areas is assumed costless. Therefore,utility is constant across space. Also, over time, we assume that each urban area attains acompetitive short-run equilibrium at every point in time (t) (see Anas 1978), such that:u(m,q)t1 u(m,q) t2 u(m,q) t3 . u(m,q) tn v ,(1)where v is constant utility. The bid rent function, obtained from the budget constraint, is themaximum rent per lot size that a household can pay for residing at distance z while enjoying afixed utility level (v). The utility function takes the following Cobb Douglas form: u maqb,where a 0, b 0, and a b 1. The bid rent function at time t is given by: y(t ) z m(t , z ) ,R( z, t ) max q ,m q(t , z ) subject to:(2)ma qb v .(3)The objective of the representative household is to choose the optimal bundle of q and m, whichcan be represented by differentiating equation (2) subject to the utility constraint (equation (3)),such that:

7 a1bq (t , z ) [ y(t ) z ] b ,(4) (t , z) a[ y(t ) z] .m(5) abwhere the constant v a , and into the bid rent function (equation (2)) yields: and mSubstituting q1 R (t , z ) [ y (t ) z ] b ,(6)where the constant θ (1-a)/ø. As explained below, equation (6) is crucial in determining theexpected city boundary.2.2 Developer problemWe assume that land development occurs at the urban periphery (i.e., undeveloped, agricultural,exterior land) and within the urban area (i.e., in currently undeveloped interior land). Theundeveloped interior land is modeled exogenously, which can take the form of leap-frogdevelopment. To insure that areas closer to CBD earn higher rent, we assume that returns toundeveloped interior land (RiA) is higher than that at the periphery (RjA). The cost of developmentis c, which by assumption does not depreciate over time. The optimal time of development is t*,which is specified as t* t s (also known as the first striking time), where s is the stopping time.Land development is irreversible due to prohibitive cost (at least in the time period underconsideration by the developer), and once developed, the land earns an urban rent R(s,z), whichdecreases as we move farther from the CBD. Therefore, the following is the price of undevelopedperipheral lot at location zj, conditional on information available at time t:P A (t , s, z) E t R j A (s, z )e r ( s t ) ds t* R j (s, z )e r ( s t ) ds ( R j A C )e r (t* t ) R(t , z ) t* (7)The first term in equation (7) is the net return to undeveloped peripheral land up to the date ofdevelopment (t*). The second term is the net return to the developed land after the date ofdevelopment. We assume that the representative developer is risk neutral and the discount rate (r)

8is constant across urban areas. With lots being the unit of development, equation (7) assumes thatthe lot size is exogenous to the developer. The equation of undeveloped interior land price is thesame as equation 7, except that returns to undeveloped interior is RAi once developed, earning areturn of Ri.We assume that the developed land rent R in either peripheral or interior areas has an exogenousstochastic pattern. We follow the literature (Capozza and Helsley, 1990; Capozza and Li, 1994;Plantinga et al., 2002) and employ a Brownian motion process with a drift g 0 and variance σ2,such that at time t s , a developed land parcel‘s rent is:R(t s, z ) R(t , z ) gs B(s)(8)Equation (8) implies that the distribution of rent after s periods is equivalent to current timeperiod (t) rent plus a drift and a random component evaluated after s periods. Capozza andHelsley (1990) assume that income is stochastic. Since rent is linear in income, due to theirassumption of fixed lot size, it follows that rent is also stochastic. In our case, income does notlinearly enter the bid-rent function (equation (6)), making the model mathematically lesstractable. Rather, we assume that the stochastic nature of rent is a consequence of exogenousshocks such as labor demand (including productivity shocks and shocks to local firms) and laborsupply shocks (e.g., Nieuwerburgh and Weill 2006; Partridge and Rickman 2003, 2006).Substituting equation (8) into (7) and integrating by parts, the expected value of an undevelopedperipheral lot is:Pt (t , z ) ARj Ar R (t , z ) g Rj A j E 2 C e r (t* t ) R(t , z ) rrr (9)A representative developer chooses the optimal time t* for converting the agricultural land intoresidential use. This occurs when the land development rent (Rj) reaches the optimal reservationrent R j . The conversion time t* is defined as: t* minS t s t R j (t s, z ) R j (10)

9From Karlin and Taylor (1975, pp. 361-362), the expected value of the Laplace transformation oft*, conditional on the initial value of development rent (R) and R , is given by: E e r (t* t ) R j (t , z ), R j e [ R j R j (t , z )](11)1where [( g 2 2 2 r ) 2 g ] / 2 . Substituting equation (11) into (9) yields: R j g R j A ( R R (t , z ))jjP (t , z ) 2 C eR j (t , z )rr r r Rj AA(12)The developer chooses R j that maximizes the land value. Differentiating equation (12) withrespect to R j yields:R j R j A rC (r g ) / r(13)where (r-αg) 0. Equation (13) reveals that the optimal reservation rent is a function of returns toundeveloped land land (RAj), cost of conversion (C), rate of change in future land developmentrent (g), and shocks to future land development rent (σ), which reflects the uncertainty effect. Thelatter is subsumed in the term (r-αg)/αr, which as discussed earlier, reflects the option valuearising from delaying the land development due to future rent uncertainty. The derivation of theinterior reservation rent ( Ri ) is the same is in equation (8-13), except that returns to interiorundeveloped land is (RAi) and returns to developed land is RAi.2.3 Density and land valueThe expected overall density at time t* can be written as the weighted average of density in theurban peripheral and interior areas:zz z*11D(t*, z*) (1 ) (t*, z ) ( i 1 / i ) (t*, z*)( j 1 / j )q 0 z q z Interior areaPeriphery(14)Where δ is the share of developed lots in urban interior. The first term of equation 14

3Bar-Ilan and Strange (1996) extend the Capozza and Helsley (1990) . linkages between uncertainty and real estate. For example, Holland et al. (2000) examined the effect of . Wu 2010), while a representative developer takes the optimal lot size as given and chooses the

Related Documents:

Sprawl development consists of three basic spatial forms: low-density continuous sprawl, ribbon sprawl, and leapfrog development sprawl (Harvey and Clark 1971). . Leapfrog development sprawl is a discontinuous

Chapter 2 Causes and Consequences of Urban Growth and Sprawl 2.1 Introduction An overall idea about urban growth and sprawl has been provided in Chap. 1. This chapter is aimed to list the causes and consequences of urban growth and sprawl. The causes that force growth in urban areas and the causes that are responsible for

1. Urban Sprawl and Urban Growth: An Age-Old Phenomenon Sprawl is directly identified with urban growth - as cities get bigger, they expand around their peripheries But sprawl is more specific, it is defined as ‘uncoordinated growth’: the expansion of a community

characterised by low population density that can manifest itself in multiple ways. The different dimensions of urban sprawl are measured by the seven indicators described in Table 1. Urban sprawl may even exist in urban areas where average population density is relatively high, if those areas contain large amounts of land where density is very low.

string searching in uncertain text [8, 1, 9, 19]. In [6] authors have studied the approximate substring matching problem, where the goal is to report the positions of all substrings of uncertain text that are similar to the query string. Re-cently, the problem of similarity search on a collection of uncertain strings has been addressed in [4].

uncertain switched linear systems may serve as a good candidate for studying uncertain nonlinear systems in a systematic way. Combine the family of discrete-time uncertain linear systems (2.1) with a class of piece-wise constant functions, : Z ! Q. Then we can de ne the following linear time-varying system as a discrete-time switched linear .

responsiveness o inflation to economic growth. The study established that there is a long relationship between economic growth and inflation. The results of the study also showed that Economic growth in Malaysia has an inelastic response to inflationary pressure. Key Words: Inflation, Economic growth, Gross savings, Imports, Malaysia.

advanced accounting program. Understanding students’ intentions in pursuing their studies to higher level of accounting courses is an important step to attract students to accounting courses. Beside intention, students’ perception on advanced accounting programs and professional courses may