Decomposition Of Sales Impact Of Stockpiling Final

3y ago
27 Views
2 Downloads
223.11 KB
54 Pages
Last View : 2m ago
Last Download : 3m ago
Upload by : Averie Goad
Transcription

Decomposition of the Sales Impact of Promotion-Induced StockpilingbyKusum L. Ailawadi*Karen Gedenk**Christian Lutzky***Scott A. Neslin****July 25, 2006*Kusum L. Ailawadi is Charles Jordan 1911 TU’12 Professor of Marketing at the Tuck School ofBusiness at Dartmouth, 100 Tuck Hall, Hanover, NH 03755, U. S. A. (Phone: 1 603 646 2845,Fax: 1 603 646 1308, e-mail: kusum.ailawadi@dartmouth.edu).**Karen Gedenk is Professor of Marketing at the University of Cologne, Department ofMarketing, Albertus-Magnus-Platz, 50923 Cologne, Germany (Phone: 49 221 470 2639, Fax: 49 221 470 5157, e-mail: gedenk@wiso.uni-koeln.de).***Christian Lutzky is a doctoral student at the University of Cologne, Department of Marketing,Albertus-Magnus-Platz, 50923 Cologne, Germany (Phone: 49 221 470 3995, Fax: 49 221 4705157, e-mail: lutzky@wiso.uni-koeln.de).****Scott A. Neslin is Albert Wesley Frey Professor of Marketing at the Tuck School of Businessat Dartmouth, 100 Tuck Hall, Hanover, NH 03755, U. S. A. (Phone: 1 603 646 2841, Fax: 1603 646 1308, e-mail: scott.neslin@dartmouth.edu).Acknowledgments: We thank session attendees at the 2004 INFORMS Marketing ScienceConference and the 2005 AMA Doctoral Consortium for their helpful comments. This researchwas supported by the German National Science Foundation (Deutsche Forschungsgemeinschaft)and the Tuck Associates Program.1

Decomposition of the Sales Impact of Promotion-Induced StockpilingABSTRACTPromotion-induced consumer stockpiling has a negative impact for manufacturers because itmoves forward in time brand sales that would have occurred later at full margin. But theresulting increase in consumer inventory also has two potential benefits, i.e., increased categoryconsumption and pre-emptive brand switches (where the additional inventory of the promotedbrand pre-empts the consumer’s purchase of a competing brand in the future). Further, there is apotential impact on repeat purchases of the stockpiled brand after the promotion. In this paper,the authors present a model and simulation based method to measure the benefits and costs ofstockpiling and assess their relative magnitude. They find that the benefits are substantial butconsumption appears to be the most important, followed by pre-emptive switching and then anincrease in repeat purchases. These benefits easily offset the negative aspect of consumerstockpiling, namely, purchase acceleration by loyal customers who would have bought the brandat regular price later.Keywords: Promotion bump, stockpiling, brand choice, repeat rates.2

Decomposition of the Sales Impact of Promotion-Induced StockpilingConsumer stockpiling is a fundamental consequence of sales promotion (Neslin 2002). Itoccurs because the promotion induces consumers to buy sooner or buy more than they wouldhave otherwise (Blattberg, Eppen, and Lieberman 1981; Neslin, Henderson, and Quelch 1985).Either way, consumers end up with more quantity than they would have had in the absence ofpromotion. Blattberg, Eppen, and Lieberman (1981) show that promotion-induced stockpilingallows retailers to transfer inventory holding costs to consumers. Evidence of consumerstockpiling is found directly in panel data analyses of purchase incidence and quantity (Bucklinand Gupta 1992; Bucklin, Gupta, and Siddarth 1998; Chintagunta and Haldar 1998; Gupta 1988),and indirectly in the detection of post-promotion dips in weekly sales data (Macé and Neslin2004; van Heerde, Leeflang, and Wittink 2000 and 2004).Whether consumer stockpiling hurts or benefits the manufacturer of the promoted branddepends upon what consumers do after the promotion. If the resultant extra household inventoryleads consumers to consume more of the category, this is a benefit to the manufacturer. We callthis the “consumption effect”. If the extra inventory pre-empts future purchases of the promotedbrand, this is a cost to the manufacturer because the manufacturer’s profit margin is typicallylower during promotion periods compared to non-promotion periods (e.g., see Neslin, Powell,and Schneider Stone 1995). We call pre-emption of the promoted brand’s future purchases“loyal acceleration.” If the extra inventory pre-empts future purchases of competing brands, thisis a benefit to the manufacturer because it takes consumers out of the market for competingbrands (Lodish 1986, p. 41). We call this “pre-emptive switching.” If the extra inventory affectsfuture brand choice after the promotion, this can either benefit or hurt the manufacturer,3

depending on whether the brand’s future purchase probability increases or decreases. We callthis the “repeat purchase effect”.Figure 1 summarizes these phenomena. The promotion sales bump consists of currentbrand switching and stockpiling. The stockpiling portion of the bump is the sum ofconsumption, pre-emptive switching, and loyal acceleration. The repeat purchase effect reflectshow stockpiling affects future brand choice, although this is not a direct component of the bump.[Figure 1 Goes About Here]Researchers recognize and have attempted to measure the consumption, loyalacceleration, and pre-emptive switching effects. Consumption effects in particular have recentlyattracted significant attention. Additional category consumption arises through new users, fewerstock-outs, and faster use-up. Ailawadi and Neslin (1998) explicitly model faster use-up, orflexible consumption, and find it to be a significant factor in the yogurt market and even to someextent in the ketchup market. Subsequent research confirms that increased consumption canaccount for a substantial portion of the promotion-induced sales bump (e.g., Bell, Chiang, andPadmanabhan 1999; Foubert 2004; van Heerde, Leeflang, and Wittink 2004).Previous research supports the existence of loyal acceleration and pre-emptive switching,although the phenomena are difficult to disentangle from post-promotion effects like the repeatpurchase effect. For example, loyal acceleration measured as a post-promotion dip in aggregatedata (e.g., Macé and Neslin 2004) may be under-estimated due to positive repeat purchase effectsor it may be exaggerated by negative repeat purchase effects. Van Heerde, Leeflang, andWittink (2004) combine pre-emptive switching and loyal acceleration in their analysis and notethat separating them is an important avenue for research. A recent working paper by van Heerdeand Gupta (2005) measures several important components of the bump, including pre-emptive4

switching and loyal acceleration, but does not separate these from post-promotion repeatpurchase effects. Chan, Narasimhan, and Zhang (2004) decompose the promotional bump intoincreased consumption of the brand, brand switching within the promotion week, brandswitching within subsequent weeks, and stockpiling of the brand. Their work providesespecially strong evidence of consumption effects, but they do not explicitly measure preemptive switching or distinguish between loyal acceleration and the repeat purchase effect.To the extent that loyal acceleration and pre-emptive switching exist, it appears that theformer is substantial. Chan, Narasimhan, and Zhang (2004) and Neslin, Henderson, and Quelch(1985) find that loyal customers are more likely to accelerate than non-loyal customers. Krishna(1994) and Sun, Neslin, and Srinivasan (2003) draw on a dynamic structural model to provide arationale for why loyal customers would be more likely to accelerate than non-loyal customers:Only for loyal customers does the consumption utility for the additional product offset theadditional household inventory cost incurred by stockpiling.Although several researchers have studied the effect of promotion on repeat rates, thedifferential effect of promotion-induced stockpiling on repeat purchases has not previously beeninvestigated. The effect could emerge as follows. Stockpiling means that the consumer usesmore of the brand before the next purchase. From a behavioral learning standpoint, this providesmore reinforcement before the next purchase, so the behavior of buying the brand is more likelyto persist (see Rothschild and Gaidis 1981). Thus, stockpiling should have a positive effect onrepeat purchases under behavioral learning. From a cognitive learning viewpoint, stockpilingprovides a longer post-purchase evaluation period (Engel, Blackwell, and Miniard 1995). Thereare then two possibilities: If involvement is high, the consumer has more time to uncover thestrengths or weaknesses of the brand (Engel, Blackwell, and Miniard 1995, pp. 263, 273-276). If5

involvement is low, stockpiling provides more time to establish inertia or induce boredom(Engel, Blackwell, and Miniard 1995, pp. 158-160). Thus, under cognitive learning, stockpilingcould yield more repeat purchases (through inertia or higher brand knowledge) or fewer repeatpurchases (through boredom or variety seeking).In summary, promotion-induced stockpiling by consumers has the potential to produceconsumption, pre-emptive switching, loyal acceleration, and repeat purchase effects. Previousresearch suggests these effects exist but has not disentangled them and assessed their individualcontribution. The purpose of this paper is to provide a unified analysis of the sales impact ofpromotion-induced stockpiling for the manufacturer. We develop a method for measuringpromotion-induced stockpiling, consumption, pre-emptive switching, loyal acceleration, andrepeat purchases, and quantify their magnitudes in two product categories. We proceed asfollows. First we describe our model and estimation method. Second, we discuss the data usedfor our empirical investigation. Next, we present the estimated model results. We then quantifythe consumption, pre-emptive switching, loyal acceleration, and repeat purchase effects ofstockpiling using a Monte Carlo simulation. We also quantify their relative magnitude infinancial terms. Finally, we discuss the implications of our work for managers and researchers.MODELOverviewWe formulate an integrated brand choice, purchase incidence and purchase quantitymodel to investigate the potential impact of promotion-induced stockpiling. As in previousincarnations of choice/incidence/quantity models, we model these decisions conditional onshopping trip and store choice (e.g., Bucklin and Lattin 1992, Tellis and Zufryden 1995):(1)Pht ( j& q) Pht (inc) * Pht ( j inc) * Pht (q inc & j)6

where:Pht(j & q)Pht(inc)Pht(j inc)Pht(q inc & j) Probability household h buys q units of brand j on shopping trip t. Probability household h purchases the category on trip t. Probability household h purchases brand j on trip t, givenhousehold h makes a category purchase. Probability household h buys q units of brand j on trip t, givenhousehold h makes a category purchase and buys brand j.The incidence and choice components of the model are handled in the nested logitframework (Ben-Akiva and Lerman 1985), the quantity model is a truncated Poisson (Mullahy1986), and we allow for flexible consumption (Ailawadi and Neslin 1998). We use a continuousmixture model to account for cross-sectional heterogeneity in model parameters. Assuming thatthe parameters are normally distributed, we estimate their mean and standard deviation (Erdem,Mayhew, and Sun 2001; Gönül and Srinivasan 1993). We do not impose a covariance structureon the random effects within and across the incidence, choice, and quantity equations to keep thecomputational burden manageable. Empirically, of course, correlations can and do occurbetween pairs of random effects. The three equations are jointly estimated using simulatedmaximum likelihood (Erdem 1996; Seetharaman 2004; Sun, Neslin, and Srinivasan 2003; Train2003).Choice ModelGiven the nested logit framework, the choice model takes the form of a multinomial logit.We add a term to the standard utility equation that allows us to investigate the repeat purchaseimpact of stockpiling. This term augments the usual state dependence parameter according towhether the brand purchased on the previous purchase occasion was purchased in a larger thanusual quantity on that occasion. We therefore have:7

(2)Pht ( j inc) eVhjt eVhktkVhjt β0hj β1h PRICE hjt β 2h PROMO hjt β3h LASThjt β 4h LPROMO hjt β5h(3)Q hjtQhwhere:PRICEhjt Regular price of brand j available to household h on shopping trip t.PROMOhjt Promotion indicator, equal to 1 if brand j available to household h onshopping trip t is on promotion; 0 otherwise.LASThjt Last brand purchased indicator for state dependence, equal to 1 ifhousehold h bought brand j on the previous purchase occasion beforeshopping trip t; 0 otherwise.LPROMOhjt Last purchase on promotion indicator, equal to 1 if household h bought jon promotion on the previous purchase occasion before shopping trip t; 0otherwise.Qhjt Quantity (ounces) bought of brand j if household h bought brand j on theprevious purchase occasion before shopping trip t; 0 otherwise.Qh Average quantity (ounces) of the category purchased per purchaseoccasion by household h during an initialization period.The new part of the model is the Q hjt / Q h term. As a result, if household h bought brand j on theprevious purchase occasion before shopping trip t, we get the following contribution to utility:(4)Contribution β3h β4h LPROMO hjt β5hQ hjtQhWe expect the state dependence term β3h to be positive per previous literature -- all elseequal, previous purchase of the brand reinforces preference and the household is more likely topurchase it on the current purchase occasion (e.g., Ailawadi, Gedenk, and Neslin 1999;Seetharaman 2004; Seetharaman, Ainslie, and Chintagunta 1999). We expect β4h to be negative,consistent with previous research showing that promotion purchases are less reinforcing than8

non-promotion purchases (Gedenk and Neslin 1999; Guadagni and Little 1983). This may bedue to a diminishing of brand attitude because the consumer attributes his or her purchase to thepromotion, not the brand (Dodson, Tybout, and Sternthal 1978).Finally, a positive β5h would mean that higher than usual purchase quantity on theprevious purchase occasion (i.e., stockpiling) result in greater purchase reinforcement, and thelikelihood is higher that the household will purchase brand j on the current purchase occasion.Therefore, β5h represents the potential repeat purchase benefit of stockpiling. As noted earlier,stockpiling may breed boredom or variety seeking, in which case β5h would be negative. Allparameters are assumed to follow a normal distribution across consumers.Incidence ModelIn the nested logit formulation, the purchase incidence model takes the form:Pht (inc) (5)(e Wht1 e Wht)(6)Wht κ 0h κ1h INVht INV h κ 2 Ch κ3h INCVAL ht(7) INCVAL ht ln e Vhkt k where:INVht Inventory (ounces) of household h on shopping trip t.INV h Average inventory (ounces) of household h during the initialization period.Ch Average daily consumption (ounces) of household h during the initializationperiod.INCVALht “Inclusive Value” for household h on shopping trip t.9

The variables in this binomial logit incidence model are standard (e.g., Ailawadi andNeslin 1998; Bucklin, Gupta, and Siddarth 1998). We allow for heterogeneity in all coefficientsexcept for κ2, the coefficient of C h , because C h only takes one value per household andtherefore cannot have a unique coefficient per household.Purchase QuantityThe purchase quantity model is a truncated Poisson (Mullahy 1986). It is written as:Pht (q inc & j) (8)λ hjt e(9)((λ hjt )q(eλ hjt(q 1, 2, , ) 1)q!)γ 0 h γ1h INVht INV h γ 2 U h γ 3 BRANDPREFhj γ 4 h PRICE hjt γ 5 h PROMOhjtwhere:Uh Average number of units purchased per purchase occasion by household hduring the initialization period.BRANDPREFhj Percentage of category purchases by household h that are of brand j duringthe initialization period.All the terms in the model are standard (e.g., Ailawadi and Neslin 1998; Bucklin, Gupta,and Siddarth 1998; Krishnamurthi and Raj 1991). We account for heterogeneity in all modelparameters except for the coefficients of U h and BRANDPREFhj since those variables only takeone value each per household.Inventory and ConsumptionOur inventory and consumption model allows for flexible consumption as in Ailawadiand Neslin (1998). Both variables are updated daily:(10)(11)INVhd INVh,d 1 Q h,d 1 CONSh,d 1 ChCONShd INVhd f Ch ( INVhd )10

where:CONShd Consumption (ounces) of household h on day d.Qhd Quantity (ounces) purchased by household h on day d.As Equation 10 makes clear, previous purchases, inventory levels, and consumption alldetermine the household’s current inventory level. In Equation 11, the parameter f reflectsconsumption flexibility. It governs the extent to which consumption increases with higher levelsof inventory. High values of f imply less flexible consumption because consumption initiallyincreases with inventory and then levels off. Low values of f imply flexible consumption, whereconsumption continually increases with inventory.EstimationThe model is estimated jointly using simulated maximum likelihood (Train 2003).1 Thelikelihood function is: Yht1 Y e Wht 1 ht eVhjtL Wht Wht eVhkthtj 1 e 1 e k (12) Zhjt λ hjt q λhjt (e 1)q! Zhjt where:Zhjt Yht Brand purchase indicator, equals 1 if household h purchased brand j on shopping tript; 0 otherwise.Category purchase indicator, equals 1 if household h purchased the category onshopping trip t; 0 otherwise.DATAWe use Nielsen scanner panel data for the ketchup and yogurt categories. The first 26weeks of the data are used for initialization and the remaining 112 weeks for estimation. In the1Simulated maximum likelihood estimates of model parameters and their standard errors can be sensitive to startingvalues and the scaling of variables. We ensured the robustness of our estimates by testing various starting valuesand by scaling the variables in our model so that all parameter estimates lay between -1 and 1. The latter proved tobe particularly important and we thank Kenneth Train for highlighting to us the importance of scaling. Of course,for ease of exposition, we report results after converting the estimates back to the original scales of the variables.11

ketchup category, we analyze the 28 and 32 ounce sizes of four brands. The selected brands andsizes account for 81.1% of all ketchup sales. In the yogurt category, we analyze all 6 and 8ounce sizes which account for 90.9% of all yogurt sales. Six of the yogurt brands have shares of5% or more and account for 84.4% of sales of the selected sizes. We aggregate the remainingseven brands into an “all-others” brand.We select households that (a) make at least one shopping trip over each four-week periodin the data; (b) purchase only the selected brands and sizes; and (c) make at least three purchasesduring the initialization period and at least one purchase during the estimation period. The firstfilter ensures that we exclude transient households. The second filter ensures that we account forall category purchases and consumption of the included households, while avoiding the need tomodel size choice (e.g., Chintagunta 1993; Jedidi, Mela, and Gupta 1999). We combine the 6and 8 ounce sizes of yogurt and the 28 and 32 ounce sizes of ketchup because consumers are notlikely to make choice and quantity decisions based on a distinction between such similar sizes.The third filter ensures that we obtain reliable values of U h , Ch , and INV h from theinitialization period, although it creates a somewhat heavier user group, especially for ketchup.[Table 1 Goes About Here]These selection criteria result in 163 households for the ketchup category and 263households for the yogurt category. We retained a random half of the 263 yogurt households tomake computing time more manageable, resulting in 131 households. As shown in Table 1, the131 yogurt households generated 30,003

leads consumers to consume more of the category, this is a benefit to the manufacturer. We call this the “consumption effect”. If the extra inventory pre-empts future purchases of the promoted . could yield more repeat purchases (through inertia or higher brand knowledge) or fewer repeat purchases (through boredom or variety seeking).

Related Documents:

2.1. Singular Value Decomposition The decomposition of singular values plays a crucial role in various fields of numerical linear algebra. Due to the properties and efficiency of this decomposition, many modern algorithms and methods are based on singular value decomposition. Singular Value Decomposition of an

A mission decomposition diagram is built to represent a hierarchical structure among the mission tasks. Different decomposition techniques (e.g., functional decomposition, goal decomposition, terrain decomposition) generally re

DBD non-thermal Plasma for decomposition of Volatile Organic Compounds S.Mohanty1, . decomposition process by Dielectric barrier Discharge (DBD) plasma assisted methods and its advantages are discussed. Decomposition . and environmental tobacco smoke [Table 2]. VOCs mostly exist in the vapor phase in the atmosphere.

Sales Planning 3 Sales Planning is a key function in the procedure of sales management process. Sales planning is an effective method that involves sales forecasting, demand management, setting profit-based sales targets, and the written execution steps of a sales plan. Sales Planning is the process of org

Overview of Sales Funnel Module Sales Sources Sales Stages Sales Opportunity Status Reasons Auto-Reminders Time-line Items Initial Setup Setting up your Sales Proposal Template. 3 Overview The GrowthZone Sales Funnel management tool empowers you to monetize and track sales opportunities such as

A key metric that Sales Managers routinely focus on is sales pipeline. Dynamics 365 provides managers with a complete view of forecasted sales, with the ability to segment the pipeline by product, by territory, by salesperson, or by sales stage. In this example the sales pipeline is displayed as a sales funnel segmented by sales stage.

Sales Management The word sales management is a combination of two words- sales and management. Sales is the art of planning in the mind of another a motive which will induce . management. 7. Motivate the Sales Force -One of the core objectives of sales management is to motivate the sales force. Selling is a very stressful task, achieving .

1.2 Sales Management: Marketing Management and the New Economy 1.3 Sales Management 1.3.1 What is Sales Management? 1.3.2 Sales Management and the Environment 1.3.3 Sales and Other Departments 1.4 The Scope of Sales Management 1.4.1 Characteristics of the Sales Job 1.4.2 Categories of Salespersons 1.4.3 The Role of a Salesperson