EQCHANGE: A World Database On Actual And Equilibrium Effective Exchange .

1y ago
11 Views
2 Downloads
4.13 MB
143 Pages
Last View : 19d ago
Last Download : 3m ago
Upload by : Kamden Hassan
Transcription

No 2017-14 – JulyWorking PaperEQCHANGE: A World Database on Actualand Equilibrium Effective Exchange RatesCécile Couharde, Anne-Laure Delatte, Carl Grekou,Valérie Mignon & Florian MorvillierHighlightsEQCHANGE is a global database of annual indicators on effective exchange rates.EQCHANGE includes two sub-databases providing information on: (i) nominal and real effective exchangerates, and (ii) equilibrium real effective exchange rates and corresponding currency misalignments foradvanced, emerging and developing countries.The first sub-database provides effective exchange rates for 187 countries computed under three differentweighting schemes and two panels of trading partners (186 and top 30) over the 1973-2016 period.The second sub-database provides behavioral equilibrium exchange rate (BEER) estimates andcorresponding currency misalignments for 182 economies over the 1973-2016 period.

CEPII Working PaperEQCHANGEAbstractThe aim of this paper is to present EQCHANGE, the new database developed by the CEPII on effective exchangerates. EQCHANGE includes two sub-databases containing data on (i) nominal and real effective exchange rates, and(ii) equilibrium real effective exchange rates and corresponding currency misalignments for advanced, emerging anddeveloping countries. More specifically, the first sub-database delivers effective exchange rates for 187 countries thatare computed under three different weighting schemes and two panels of trading partners (186 and top 30) over the1973-2016 period. The second sub-database provides behavioral equilibrium exchange rate (BEER) estimates andcorresponding currency misalignments for 182 economies over the 1973-2016 period. We describe the constructionof the two datasets and illustrate some possible uses by presenting results concerning the evolution and maincharacteristics of currency misalignments in the world from 2015 to 2016. By providing publicly available indicators ofequilibrium exchange rates, EQCHANGE aims to contribute to key debates in international macroeconomics.KeywordsExchange Rates, Equilibrium Exchange Rates, Currency Misalignments.JELF31, C23, C82.Working PaperCEPII (Centre d’Etudes Prospectives etd’Informations Internationales) is a French institutededicated to producing independent, policyoriented economic research helpful to understandthe international economic environmentand challenges in the areas of trade policy,competitiveness, macroeconomics, internationalfinance and growth.CEPII Working PaperContributing to research in internationaleconomics CEPII, PARIS, 2017All rights reserved. Opinions expressedin this publication are those of theauthor(s) alone.Editorial Director:Sébastien JeanProduction:Laure BoivinNo ISSN: 1293-2574CEPII113, rue de Grenelle75007 Paris 33 1 53 68 55 00www.cepii.frPress contact: presse@cepii.fr

CEPII Working PaperEQCHANGEEQCHANGE: A World Database on Actual and Equilibrium E ective ExchangeRates1* and Florian Cécile Couharde , Anne-Laure Delatte , Carl Grekou , Valérie Mignon¶Morvillier1. IntroductionThe widening and persistence of current account disequilibria at the international level i.e., global imbalances have refocused real exchange rate distortions at the coreof international debates.excessive imbalances?i.e.What are the exchange rate adjustments needed to correctHow to assess whether a currency is fundamentally misaligned,under- or over-valued?Due to the key role played by currency misalignments ineconomic research and policy analysis, several institutions publish various indicators thatrely on more or less sophisticated measures.To establish whether a currency is misaligned, and, if so, to which extent, a rough assessment can be obtained from the Big Mac index (BMI) developed since 1986 byEconomist.TheWhen compared to the actual exchange rate, this BMI gives an indicationof the extent to which a currency is over- or undervalued according to the law of one2price.This measure is freely downloadable from the website ofThe Economist ;3butit only assesses the purchasing power between two countries in terms of a single good.Therefore, this indicator should not be interpreted systematically as indication of misalignment. This shortcoming is acknowledged byThe Economistcommenting that theWe are grateful to Philip Lane for kindly providing us with data on net foreign asset positions and toSébastien Jean for helpful remarks and suggestions.EconomiX-CNRS, University of Paris Nanterre, France. Email: cecile.couharde@parisnanterre.fr.CEPII, Griswold, CNRS and CEPR. Email: anne-laure.delatte@cepii.fr.EconomiX-CNRS, University of Paris Nanterre and CEPII, France. Email: carl.grekou@cepii.fr.EconomiX-CNRS, University of Paris Nanterre and CEPII, France. Corresponding author : ValérieMignon, EconomiX-CNRS, University of Paris Nanterre, 200 avenue de la République, 92001 NanterreCedex, France. Phone: 33 1 40 97 58 60. E-mail: valerie.mignon@parisnanterre.frEconomiX-CNRS, University of Paris Nanterre and CEPII, ut simply, if the Big Mac costs x% more in a country than in a country , then the currency of countrywill be % overvalued relative to the currency of country .http://www.economist.com/content/big-mac-index1* ¶2i3ixjj3

CEPII Working PaperEQCHANGEBig Mac index is merely a tool to make exchange-rate theory more digestible .Several institutions have developed more sophisticated measures that di er from theBMI framework in various ways.First, these measures do not rely on a bilateral ex-change rate as the BMI, but on the real e ective i.e., multilateral exchange rate(REER). Therefore, the misalignment of a currency is not measured against only oneparticular currency, but instead against an average index of a whole basket of currencies.Second, currency misalignments are calculated from the assessment of an equilibriumvalue of the REER, i.e. a value of the REER that is consistent with the macroeconomicbalances (both internal and external) over the medium to the long term and given aset of fundamentals.The major advantage of this methodology over the simple BMIframework is that it allows the equilibrium value of the exchange rate to vary over time,re ecting changes in economic fundamentals.4However, the lack of consensus on the de nition of equilibrium exchange rates has madeit very di cult to establish a unique approach (MacDonald, 2000; Driver and Westaway, 2004). Therefore, several equilibrium exchange rate methodologies exist and theyare usually classi ed into three complementary groups: (1) the macroeconomic balanceapproach; (2) the behavioral equilibrium exchange rate (BEER) approach; and (3) theexternal sustainability approach.The macroeconomic balance approach calculates thedi erence between the current account (CA) projected over the medium term at prevailing exchange rates and an estimated equilibrium current account, or CA norm . TheBEER approach directly estimates an equilibrium real exchange rate for each country asa function of medium- to long-term fundamentals of the REER. The external sustainability approach calculates the di erence between the actual current account balance andthe balance that would stabilize the net foreign asset position of the country at somebenchmark level.Since the mid-1990s, the practice of the IMF, more precisely of theExchange Rate IssuesConsultative Group on(CGER), consists in using these three complementary approachesto provide exchange rate assessments for a number of advanced economies and emergingmarket countries (IMF, 2006). According to the IMF, using a broad range of indicatorsand other analytical tools provides the best possible estimate of the equilibrium exchangerate level.But, the information delivered by the IMF is not timely consistent, as it ishas however improved the assessment of the BMI by introducing in 2011 an adjustedBig Mac index which controls for income per capita di erential between countries.4The Economist4

CEPII Working PaperEQCHANGEproduced on an irregular basis, and it only concerns a limited sample of countries.5Cline and Williamson (2008) have started a semi-annual estimate of fundamental equilibrium exchange rates (FEERs) for 35 countries, publicly available on the AmericanPeterson Institute for International Economics (PIIE) website.6The issue of currency misalignments has also been in the research agenda of the Centred'Etudes Prospectives et d'Informations Internationales (CEPII), a French governmentfunded research center focusing on the world economy.Since 2004, the CEPII hasirregularly produced and published estimates of currency misalignments mainly based on7 i.e. the second methodology employed by the IMF's CGER.the BEER approach,In sum, each aforementioned institute computes its own equilibrium real exchange rates(ERER), but there is no publicly available database providing these ERER and corresponding currency misalignments for a consistent and large sample of countries over along period of time. In order to bridge the gap, the CEPII has developed a new databaseEQCHANGEcovering the largest sample of countries, thee ective exchange rates and(ii)database, from which(i)estimates of equilibrium real exchange rates and ofcurrency misalignments can be freely downloaded.The rst sub-database, on e ective exchange rates, provides indices of nominal andreal e ective exchange rates for 187 economies over the 1973-2016 period.The ef-fective exchange rates indices are calculated for two panels of trade partners (186 andtop 30) and using di erent weighting systems.Therefore, theEQCHANGEdatabasebrings a host of new features that greatly enhance the calculation of e ective exchangerates compared to existing annual databases in terms of country/time coverage andmethodological options (i.e., number of trade partners and weighting schemes).For example, IMF country reports do not necessarily include CGER assessments. Indeed, they cancontain the ndings of separate analyses, as IMF's working papers, central bank studies, and periodicreports of investment banks. In addition, the panel of considered countries varies across studies.While the FEER approach consists in ad hoc determination of current account norms, in the original macroeconomic balance approach these targets are obtained from the estimation of an equilibrium current account equation (see Williamson, 1994, and Cline, 2008, for details). Note further thatthe PIIE started publishing the data for a number of advanced countries and emerging economies in2008. Access: -2016The rst working paper related to misalignments assessments was published in 2004 (Bénassy-Quéréet al., 2004). A recent publication reports estimates of currency misalignments within the euro area(Couharde et al., 2017; see also Coudert et al., 2013). For the sake of completeness, note that someCEPII studies have also provided misalignments based on the FEER approach, see e.g. Bénassy-Quéré etal. (2008) and Carton and Hervé (2013).5675

CEPII Working PaperEQCHANGEThe substantial enhancement introduced byEQCHANGElays in the second sub-databasewhich includes assessments of equilibrium real e ective exchange rates and correspondingcurrency misalignments. More precisely, we estimate ERER based on the BEER approach(Clark and MacDonald, 1998). We have chosen this framework as it allows us to provideseveral ERER estimates for the vast majority of countries in the world (182 countries) andover a reasonably long time-span (from 1973 to 2016). Currency misalignments are thendeduced from the di erence between real e ective exchange rates and their equilibriumvalues; we calculate various misalignments, depending on the de nition of real e ectiveexchange rates indices (weighting schemes di er for example), the speci cation of theequilibrium exchange rate model and the sample of countries.By providing publicly available indicators of equilibrium exchange rates, our databasehelps documenting key debates such as the role of exchange rates on global and/orregional imbalances, the use of exchange rate as a mercantilist tool, the impact ofcurrency misalignments on resources' reallocation between the tradable and the nontradable sectors and on economic growth, to name a few.The primary objective of this paper is to provide a comprehensive account of our methodological framework to calculate its set of e ective exchange rates and of equilibrium realexchange rates from which currency misalignments are derived. To this end, Section 2is devoted to the presentation of the main features of theEQCHANGEdatabase. Asan illustration, Section 3 presents the evolution and essential characteristics of currencymisalignments in the world from 2015 to 2016. Section 4 concludes the paper.2. The EQCHANGE databaseTheEQCHANGEdatabase developed by the CEPII consists of time series of: nominal and real e ective exchange rates (Section 2.1); behavioral equilibrium exchanges rates and resulting currency misalignments (Section2.2).2.1. The e ective exchange rates datasetSeveral institutions, such as the World Bank (WB), the International Monetary Fund(IMF), the Bank of International Settlements (BIS), or think tanks such as Bruegel publish more or less regularly indexes of nominal and real e ective exchange rates. The6

CEPII Working PaperEQCHANGEFigure 1 E ective exchange rates dataset: country coverageEQCHANGEdatabase developed by the CEPII has two distinct characteristics whencompared to those databases.First, theEQCHANGEdatabase has the widest coun-try/time coverage as we compute annual e ective exchange rates (both in nominal andreal terms) for 187 countries over the 1973-2016 period (see the list of countries inAppendix A.1, and Figure 1).Second, by using a simple export weighting method, theEQCHANGEdatabase includese ective exchange rates indices calculated and available along various dimensions, including the weighting scheme and trading partners' coverage. Therefore our database allowsthe adoption of alternate options for the selection of data.rates indices are available for two weighting schemes.Firstly, e ective exchangeThe rst one is time-invariantand consists in two weight sets respectively representative of foreign trade between2008-2012, and(ii )1973-2016.(i )The second weighting system is time-varying and isessentially based on non-overlapping ve-year average weights.8Secondly, e ective ex-change rates rely on broad-based and narrow-based indices which are calculated againsttwo main groups of trading partners, i.e. against 186 trading partners and the top 30trading partners for each country. Di erences between our database and other ones arereported in Table 1.The following periods 1973-1979; 1980-1984; 1985-1989; 1990-1994; 1995-1999; 2000-2004; 20052009; 2010-2016 have been considered.87

CoverageCountries PeriodTypeWeighting systemPeriod CEPII187(i)1973-2016(ii)FixedTime-varying1973 20162008 2012Basket186 and 30Data frequencyUpdatesAnnualRegularly5-year rly andRegularlyAnnualFixedTime varyingFixed1998-20031-year window2011-2013Notes: the column "Basket" indicates the number of trade partners used to calculate the ANGEBIS(i)(ii)(iii)(iv)CEPII Working PaperDatabaseTable 1 Comparison of various datasets

CEPII Working PaperEQCHANGE2.1.1. Methodological featuresAn e ective exchange rate measures the rate at which a country's currency exchangesagainst a basket of other currencies, in either nominal or real terms.iThe nominal e ective exchange rate of countryvalue of the currency of countryiin periodt (NEERi ;t )measures theagainst a weighted average of foreign currencies:NEERi ;t NYjNERwi j;t(1)i j;t 1NER is the index of the nominal bilateral exchange rate between the currency9of country i and the currency of its trade partners j in period t , N denotes the number10of trading partners and wis the trade-based weight associated to the partner j .wherei j;ti j;tThe real e ective exchange rate of countryiin periodt (REERi ;t )weighted average of real bilateral exchange rates against each of itsis calculated as theNtrading partnersj:REERi ;t NYRERi j;tof the country NERP Pi j;tii ;twi j;t(2)i j;tjwhereRER 1is an index of the real exchange rate of the currencyj;tjvis-à-vis the currency of the trading partnerstand respectively for the price index of countryiin periodand of countryt. Pi ;tandPj;tj.With these de nitions, a real (nominal) appreciation of the domestic currency is recordedas an increase in the real (nominal) e ective exchange rate index.Constructing an e ective exchange rate index (both in nominal and real terms) for agiven country then requires determining the trade-weight associated to each of its partners. In many circumstances, the exchange rate plays the role of a relative price of tradedgoods; hence, the relevant weights usually involve trade weights. Moreover, in most openeconomies, policy-makers are more interested in the total international competitive position of their country. In this case, appropriate e ective exchange rate measures shouldinclude both import and export weights.Computing import weights is fairly straight-The nominal exchange rate is expressed as the number of foreign currency units per domestic currency.An increase therefore corresponds to an appreciation of the domestic currencyagainst the foreign currency.PThese weights are normalized so that their sum is equal to one, i.e. 1.910Nj9 1 wi j;t

CEPII Working PaperEQCHANGEforward: import weights are based on bilateral imports, i.e. on the relative importanceof each of the partner countries,j,in total imports of a countryi.Turning to exportweights, various procedures exist including bilateral and double export weighting schemes.We prefer here to follow the bilateral-based approach for its simplicity and transparencyproperties. Indeed, this procedure is based on bilateral exports and therefore takes intoaccount only competition between the domestic country and its direct trading partners.In doing this, we have chosen not to consider the possible indirect competition on thethird markets based on the calculation of a double export weight. Speci cally, international institutions such as the IMF, the WB and the BIS construct their real e ectiveexchange rate series attempting to capture third market e ects. Compared to our simpleweighting procedure, the double export weights method contains additional informationi 's exporters in each given foreign market from ex11 However, whileporters of the countries included in the group of the N trading partners.on the competition faced by countrydelivering a more rigorous assessment of the export competition in foreign markets, thisweighting scheme can lead to a smaller area and time coverage and provides less exibility in updating the dataset, because of limitations in data availability. In particular, theinclusion of the gross value of the domestically produced supply of manufactured goodsin the calculation of the double export weight tends to restrict the number of countriesthat can be considered. In addition, if we compare our calculated overall weights (seeparagraph below) to those of the IMF, we do not observe any signi cant di erences. Wetherefore conclude that our simpler approach is broadly equivalent to that of the IMFwhen considering the overall weights. All these reasons justify our choice to not replicatethe double export weighting scheme.The overall weight of each partnerj in the trade of country iat periodt (wi j;t )is obtainedas the weighted average of the export and import weights:W M M Xi j;ti ;twhereandMWI mpi j;ti ;tand i ;ti ;t WI mpi j;t X M Xi ;ti ;tWXare total imports and total exports of countryi ;tEx pare partner country WEx pi j;tandi j;tj 's i ;t(3)import and export weights, respectivelyi.Indeed, under this approach, the export weight for any country is derived as a combination of two components: a bilateral export weight, which accounts for direct competition between exporters and domesticproducers in a particular export market; and a third-market export weight, which captures competitionbetween exporters from two di erent countries in a third market. The methodology is detailed in Turnerand Van't dack (1993).1110

CEPII Working PaperEQCHANGEThe import and export weights (Equations (4) and (5)) of each partneras its simple share of countryI mpi j;tWEx pi j;tXji ;tMji ;tare calculatedi 's imports and exports:Wwherej M Mi ;t(4) X Xi ;t(5)ji ;tji ;tdenotes import ows into the countrydenotes export ows of countryito marketjifrom countryduring periodjduring periodt,andt.2.1.2. DataE ective exchange rates are computed from the bilateral exchange rate with the USdollar of each country. The primary data source for bilateral exchange rates is the WorldBank's World Development Indicators (WDI). Other alternative sources such as nationalcentral bank statistics or the Penn World tables (9.0)12 have also been used in the caseof incomplete data (see Table A.2.1 in Appendix A.2).The price series used to de ate the bilateral nominal exchange rates are the most commonly used price series, i.e.Consumer Price Index (CPI). Although there are theo-retical reasons to prefer other types of price indexes when measuring competitiveness(Rosensweig, 1987), CPIs have the advantage of being timely and available for a widearray of countries over a long time period (see Table A.2.2 in Appendix A.2).2.1.3. Empirical comparisons for robustness checksAs e ective exchange rates can be calculated by using di erent weighting schemes,we report the correlations between the nominal (resp.real) e ective exchange ratesof our database and those provided by other databases in Table A.3.1 (resp.in Appendix A.3.A.3.2)Table A.3.1 shows that in most cases, there is a strong correlationbetween the di erent databases' nominal e ective exchange rates (NEERs). In contrast,the correlations for real e ective exchange rates (REERs) are weaker but, compared tothe Bruegel's REERs, the CEPII's REERs present higher correlations with those providedby the IMF and the WB (Table A.3.2).However, the statistical reliability of thosePWT 9.0 can be downloaded via the University of Groningen webpage athttp://www.rug.nl/ggdc/productivity/pwt/1211

CEPII Working PaperEQCHANGEcorrelations is limited, due to the relatively small number of common observations. Inorder to get a proper/meaningful comparison of the di erent series and for illustrativepurposes, we have reported in Figures C.1 and C.2 in Appendix C the evolution ofthe NEERs and REERs provided by the di erent datasets.As shown, we validate ourcalculations as the dynamics of our exchange rates indices quite follow those issued fromthe di erent databases.2.2. The database on equilibrium real exchange rates and currency misalignmentsIn this section we outline the construction of this second database and also discuss theunderlying methodology and data sources. The dataset computes equilibrium real e ective exchange rates and currency misalignments from 1973 to 2016, for 182 economies,i.e. the largest coverage with available data (Figure 2).13Figure 2 The equilibrium real exchange rates dataset: country coverageNote: the di erent shades of grey indicate the temporal coverage of the series: the darker, the longer is the temporalcoverage.This database has three distinct characteristics. First, it is the rst database on equilibrium real e ective exchange rates and currency misalignments with a global coverage.Second, we rely on the BEER approach rather than the purchasing power parity (PPP)approach. Our measures are then less restrictive than those derived from the PPP only(as the Big Mac Index for example). Moreover, BEER estimates are a good alternative toFor few economies such as countries of the former Soviet Union, series of equilibrium exchange ratesstart later, due to data availability.1312

CEPII Working PaperEQCHANGEFEER assessments such as those provided by the Peterson Institute for InternationalEconomics as the underpinning methodologythe internal and external balances, andnet foreign asset position.(i ) does not require assumptions about(ii ) takes into account stock e ects through theThird, we compute various series of equilibrium exchangerates and currency misalignments along a large set of assumptions used for the equilibrium exchange rate model, for the measure of REER, and for the coverage of partners'countries.2.2.1. Equilibrium exchange ratesThe BEER approach.We rely on the BEER approach to assess equilibrium real ex-change rates (see Clark and MacDonald, 1998).Indeed, one of the di culties whencomputing equilibrium exchange rates is to identify the long-run equilibrium path of theeconomy. We have opted for the BEER approach which is more pragmatic, as it doesnot require to estimate or to make assumptions on the long-run values of the economicfundamentals (such as current account norms for instance) as in the macroeconomic14balance approach.Instead, the BEER approach consists in assessing directly the equi-librium level of real exchange rates through the estimation of a long-run relationshipbetween real exchange rates and their fundamentals.simple and easy to implement and requires few data.This approach is then relativelyThis point is crucial given thepaucity of reliable data in several developing and emerging economies.Analyses di er in the choice of real exchange rates' fundamentals, in part because ofcountries' sample considerations. Edwards (1988), Elbadawi (1994), Hinkle and Montiel(1999) and Elbadawi and Soto (2008) among others have provided suitable theoretical frameworks that identify potential drivers of real exchange rates in developing andemerging countries. In particular, the major fundamentals behind long-run movementsof the real exchange rate identi ed for these countries are usually the terms of trade, therelative productivity of the tradable sector and the net foreign asset position, as we willdetail below.15For the advanced economies, Faruqee (1995), followed by Alberola et al.We do not postulate that the BEER methodology achieves superior performance against other equilibriumexchange rate approaches. Indeed, all these approaches, far from being opposed to each other, are rathercomplementary insofar as they assess equilibrium exchange rates over di erent time horizons (BénassyQuéré et al., 2010).For the sake of completeness and as a robustness check, we have also included in our analysis othervariables considered to be of importance to the exchange rate determination for developing countriessuch as government spending, remittances, nancial development, aid ows, and openness. However,employing such variables dramatically reduce the size of the sample (both in terms of temporal andindividual dimensions). Furthermore, the inclusion of these additional variables did not change the results141513

CEPII Working PaperEQCHANGE(1999) and Alberola (2003), have proposed a stock- ow model for the exchange ratedetermination in the long run, based on the balance-of-payments approach which emphasizes the accumulation of external disequilibria and the Balassa-Samuelson hypothesiswhich underscores relative productivity trends (Balassa, 1964; Samuelson, 1964).The empirical framework.In line with this literature, the three following variables areincluded in our regressions as fundamentals of the real exchange rate:(i)a measure ofsectoral productivity relative to trading partners to account for the Balassa-Samuelsone ect,(ii)the economy's net foreign asset position, and(iii)the economy's terms oftrade.However, rather than pooling directly together in the same equation these threefundamentals, we adopt a sequential approach by starting with the most parsimoniousregression model including only one variable and then by adding successively the otherfundamentals in the regression model.Then, the rst model (Model 1) we considerincludes only a measure of relative productivity and is drawn on the ndings that theBalassa-Samuelson e ect (BS, thereafter) is the most important economic force shapingreal exchange rate behavior. Equilibrium exchange rates derived from this rst model canbe interpreted as PPP-based equilibrium exchange rates adjusted by the BS e ect. Wealso estimate two additional models which augment Model 1 by addingasset position (Model 2), and(i ) the net foreign(ii ) the net foreign position and the terms of trade (Model3):reeri ;treeri ;treeri ;t i1 BS " iBSi ;t i1i ;t BSi ;t2nf ai ;t2 nf ai ;t3(Model 1)i ;ttoti ;t "i ;t "i ;t(Model 2)(Model 3)reer denotes the real e ective exchange rate expressed in logarithm; BS ,nf a and tot stand respectively for the BS e ect proxy (expressed in logarithm), thewherei ;ti ;ti ;ti ;tnet foreign asset position (in percentage of GDP) and the terms of trade (expressed inlogarithm). irepresents country- xed e ects and"distributed error term.in any substantial way. The results are available upon request.14i ;tis an independent and identically

CEPII Working PaperEQCHANGEThe improvement of these three fundamentals is expected to appreciate the equilibriumreal exchange rate. First, the Balassa-Samuelson e ect describes the convergence process of an economy which results in an appreciation of its real exchange rate through alarger productivity growth in the domestic traded goods.16If the real appreciation is inline with the stage of development, the currency of the country will then not necessarilybe overvalued.Second, the connection between real exchange rates and net foreign assets derives fromth

e ective exchange rates and (ii) estimates of equilibrium real exchange rates and of currency misalignments can be freely downloaded. The rst sub-database, on e ective exchange rates, provides indices of nominal and real e ective exchange rates for 187 economies over the 1973-2016 period. The ef-

Related Documents:

Database Applications and SQL 12 The DBMS 15 The Database 16 Personal Versus Enterprise-Class Database Systems 18 What Is Microsoft Access? 18 What Is an Enterprise-Class Database System? 19 Database Design 21 Database Design from Existing Data 21 Database Design for New Systems Development 23 Database Redesign 23

Getting Started with Database Classic Cloud Service. About Oracle Database Classic Cloud Service1-1. About Database Classic Cloud Service Database Deployments1-2. Oracle Database Software Release1-3. Oracle Database Software Edition1-3. Oracle Database Type1-4. Computing Power1-5. Database Storage1-5. Automatic Backup Configuration1-6

real world about which data is stored in a database. Database Management System (DBMS): A collection of programs to facilitate the creation and maintenance of a database. Database System DBMS Database A database system contains information about a particular enterprise. A database system provides an environment that is both

The term database is correctly applied to the data and their supporting data structures, and not to the database management system. The database along with DBMS is collectively called Database System. A Cloud Database is a database that typically runs on a Cloud Computing platform, such as Windows Azure, Amazon EC2, GoGrid and Rackspace.

Creating a new database To create a new database, choose File New Database from the menu bar, or click the arrow next to the New icon on the Standard toolbar and select Database from the drop-down menu. Both methods open the Database Wizard. On the first page of the Database Wizard, select Create a new database and then click Next. The second page has two questions.

2 Installing Oracle Database and Creating a Database 2.1 Overview of Installing Oracle Database Software and Creating a Database 2-1 2.1.1 Checking Oracle Database Installation Prerequisites 2-2 2.1.2 Deciding on Oracle Database Installation Choices 2-3 2.1.2.1 Install Option for Oracle Database 2-3 2.1.2.2 Installation Class for Oracle .

To disconnect from a database server, right-click the database server and click Disconnect. When you are not connected to a database server, there will be a red X on the database server icon. Connect to a database server To reconnect to the database server, either double-click it or right-click it and click Connect.

The Advanced Higher Biology question paper brief on the following page gives the structure of the SQA question paper , and the range of marks allocated to scientific problem-solving skills and knowledge and understanding. It gives the abbreviated codes for the knowledge and skills that are assessed. The question paper brief is a useful starting point to ensure that your questions have the .