Intermediate Macroeconomics

3y ago
140 Views
9 Downloads
6.37 MB
1.0K Pages
Last View : Today
Last Download : 3m ago
Upload by : Allyson Cromer
Transcription

Intermediate MacroeconomicsJulio Garı́nRobert LesterClaremont McKenna CollegeColby CollegeEric SimsUniversity of Notre DameAugust 2, 2018This Version: 3.0.0

This is a book designed for use in an intermediate macroeconomics course or a masterslevel course in macroeconomics. It could also be used by graduate students seeking a refresherin advanced undergraduate macroeconomics. This book represents a substantial makeoverand extension of the course notes for intermediate macroeconomics which have been providedpublicly on Eric Sims’s personal website for several years.There are many fine textbooks for macroeconomics at the intermediate level currentlyavailable. These texts include, but are certainly not limited to, Mankiw (2016), Williamson(2014), Jones (2013), Barro (1997), Abel, Bernanke, and Croushore (2017), Gordon (2012),Hall and Pappell (2005), Blanchard (2017), Dornbusch, Fischer, and Startz (2013), Froyen(2013), and Chugh (2015).Given the large number of high quality texts already on the market, why the need fora new one? We view our book as fulfilling a couple of important and largely unmet needsin the existing market. First, our text makes much more use of mathematics than mostintermediate books. Second, whereas most textbooks divide the study of the macroeconomyinto two “runs” (the long run and the short run), we focus on three runs – the long run, themedium run, and the short run. Third, we have attempted to emphasize the microeconomicunderpinnings of modern macroeconomics, all the while maintaining tractability and a focuson policy. Fourth, we include a section on banking, bank runs, bond pricing, and the stockmarket. While this material is generally left to money, credit, and banking texts, the recentGreat Recession has taught us the importance of thinking seriously about the implicationsof the financial system for the macroeconomy. Finally, we feel that a defining feature ofthis text is that it is, if nothing else, thorough – we have tried hard to be very clear aboutmathematical derivations and to not skip steps when doing them.Modern economics is increasingly quantitative and makes use of math. While it isimportant to emphasize that math is only a tool deployed to understand real-world phenomena,it is a highly useful tool. Math clearly communicates ideas which are often obfuscated whenonly words are used. Math also lends itself nicely to quantitative comparisons of modelswith real-world data. Our textbook freely makes use of mathematics, more so than mostof the texts we cited above. An exception is Chugh (2015), who uses more math than wedo. To successfully navigate this book, a student needs to be proficient at high school levelalgebra and be comfortable with a couple of basic rules of calculus and statistics. We haveincluded Appendices A and B to help students navigate the mathematical concepts whichare used throughout the book. While we find the approach of freely integrating mathematicsinto the analysis attractive, we recognize that it may not be well-suited for all students andall instructors. We have therefore written the book where the more involved mathematicalanalysis is contained in Part III. This material can be skipped at the instructor’s discretion,1

which allows an instructor to spend more time on the more graphical analysis used in PartsIV and V.Traditionally, macroeconomic analysis is divided into the “long run” (growth) and the“short run” (business cycles). We have added a third run to the mix, which we call the“medium run.” This is similar to the approach in Blanchard (2017), although we reverseordering relative to Blanchard, studying the long run first, then the medium run, then theshort run. Our principal framework for studying the long run in Part II is the canonical Solowmodel. We are attracted to this framework because it clearly elucidates the important role ofproductivity in accounting for both long run growth and cross-country income differences. Adrawback is that the Solow model does not formally model microeconomic decision-making,as we do throughout the rest of the book. To that end, we have also included Chapter 8using an overlapping generations framework with optimizing agents. This framework toucheson many of the same issues as the Solow model, but allows us to address a number of otherissues related to efficiency and the role of a government.Whereas growth theory studies the role of capital accumulation and productivity growthover the span of decades, we think of the medium run as focusing on frequencies of timemeasured in periods of several years. Over this time horizon, investment is an importantcomponent of fluctuations in output, but it is appropriate to treat the stock of physicalcapital as approximately fixed. Further, nominal frictions which might distort the short runequilibrium relative to an efficient outcome are likely not relevant over this time horizon.Our framework for studying the medium run is what we call the neoclassical model (or realbusiness cycle model). In this framework, output is supply determined and the equilibrium isefficient. The microeconomic underpinnings of the neoclassical model are laid out in Part IIIand a full graphical treatment is given in Part IV.We think of the short run as focusing on periods of time spanning months to several years.Our framework for studying the short run is a New Keynesian model with sticky prices. Thisanalysis is carried out in Part V. The only difference between our medium and short runmodels is the assumption of price rigidity, which makes the AS curve non-vertical – otherwisethe models are the same. We consider two different versions of the sticky price model – onein which the price level is completely predetermined within period (the simple sticky pricemodel) and another in which the price level is sensitive to the output gap (the partial stickyprice model). With either form of price stickiness, demand shocks matter, and the scope forbeneficial short run monetary and/or fiscal policies becomes apparent. Optimal monetarypolicy and complications raised by the zero lower bound (ZLB) are addressed. Appendix Ddevelops a sticky wage model which has similar implications to the sticky price model.Modern macroeconomics is simply microeconomics applied at a high level of aggregation.2

To that end, we have devoted an entire part of the book, Part III, to the “Microeconomics ofMacroeconomics.” There we study an optimal consumption-saving problem, a firm profitmaximization problem in a dynamic setting, equilibrium in an endowment economy, anddiscuss fiscal policy, money, and the First Welfare Theorem. Whereas for the most part weignore unemployment throughout the book and instead simply focus on total labor input, wealso include a chapter on search, matching, and unemployment. The analysis carried out inPart III serves as the underpinning for the remainder of the medium and short run analysisin the book, but we have tried to write the book where an instructor can omit Part III shouldhe or she choose to do so.Relatedly, modern macroeconomics takes dynamics seriously. We were initially attractedto the two period macroeconomic framework used in Williamson (2014), for which Barro(1997) served as a precursor. We have adopted this two period framework for Parts III throughV. That said, our experience suggested that the intertemporal supply relationship (due toan effect of the real interest rate on labor supply) that is the hallmark of the Williamson(2014) approach was ultimately confusing to students. It required spending too much timeon a baseline market-clearing model of the business cycle and prevented moving more quicklyto a framework where important policy implications could be addressed. We have simplifiedthis by assuming that labor supply does not depend on the real interest rate. This can bemotivated formally via use of preferences proposed in Greenwood, Hercowitz, and Huffman(1988), which feature no wealth effect on labor supply.We were also attracted to the timeless IS-LM approach as laid out, for example, soeloquently by Mankiw (2016), Abel, Bernanke, and Croushore (2017), and others. Part Vstudies a short run New Keynesian model, freely making use of the commonly deployedIS-LM-AD-AS analysis. The medium run model we develop graphically in part IV can becast in this framework with a vertical AS curve, which is often called the “long run supplycurve” (or LRAS) in some texts. Because of our simplification concerning the dynamic natureof labor supply in Part IV, we can move to the short run analysis in Part V quicker. Also,because the medium run equilibrium is efficient and the medium run can be understood as aspecial case of the short run, the policy implications in the short run become immediatelyclear. In particular, policy should be deployed in such a way that the short run equilibrium(where prices are sticky) coincides with the medium run equilibrium. Price stability is oftena good normative goal, and monetary policy ought to target the natural or neutral rateof interest, which is the interest rate which would obtain in the absence of price or wagerigidities. This “Wicksellian” framework for thinking about policy is now the dominantparadigm for thinking about short run fluctuations in central banks. Within the context ofthe IS-LM-AD-AS model, we study the zero lower bound and an open economy version of3

the model. Jones (2013) proposes replacing the LM curve with the monetary policy (MP)curve, which is based on a Taylor rule type framework for setting interest rates. We includean appendix, Appendix E, where the MP curve replaces the LM curve.Finally, the recent Great Recession has highlighted the importance of thinking aboutconnections between the financial system and the macroeconomy. Part VI of the book isdedicated to studying banking, financial intermediation, and asset pricing in more depth. Weinclude chapters on the basics of banking and bank runs, as well as a chapter that delves intothe money supply process in more detail. We also have detailed chapters on bond and stockpricing in a dynamic, optimizing framework based on the stochastic discount factor. Much ofthis material is traditionally reserved for money, credit, and banking courses, but we thinkthat recent events make the material all the more relevant for conventional macroeconomicscourses. Chapter 35 incorporates an exogenous credit spread variable into our medium/shortrun modeling framework and argues that exogenous increases in credit spreads are a sensibleway to model financial frictions and crises. Chapter 36 provides an in-depth accounting of therecent financial crisis and Great Recession and deploys the tools developed elsewhere in thebook to understand the recession and the myriad policy interventions undertaken in its wake.In writing this book, we have tried to follow the lead of Glenmorangie, the distillerymarketing itself as producing Scotch that is “unnecessarily well-made.” In particular, wehave attempted throughout the book to be unnecessarily thorough. We present all the stepsfor various mathematical derivations and go out of our way to work through all the stepswhen deriving graphs and shifting curves. This all makes the book rather than longer thanit might otherwise be. In a sense, it is our hope that a student could learn from this textwithout the aid of a formal instructor, though we think this is suboptimal. Our preferencefor this approach is rooted in our own experiences as students, where we found ourselvesfrustrated (and often confused) when instructors or textbooks skipped over too many details,instead preferring to focus on the “big picture.” There is no free lunch in economics, andour approach is not without cost. At present, the book is short on examples and real-worldapplications. We hope to augment the book along these dimensions in the coming monthsand years. The best real world examples are constantly changing, and this is an area wherethe instructor contributes some value added, helping to bring the text material to life.The book is divided into six main parts. Part I serves as an introduction. Chapter 1reviews some basic definitions of aggregate macroeconomic variables. While most studentsshould have seen this material in a principles course, we think it is important for them tosee it again. Chapter 2 defines what an economic model is and why a model is useful. Thischapter motivates the rest of the analysis in the book, which is based on models. Chapter 3provides a brief overview of the history and controversies of macroeconomics.4

We study the long run in Part II. We put the long run first, rather than last as in manytextbooks, for two main reasons. First, growth is arguably much more important for welfarethan is the business cycle. As Nobel Prize winner Robert Lucas once famously said, “Once youstart to think about growth, it is difficult to think about anything else.” Second, the standardSolow model for thinking about growth is not based on intertemporal optimization, butrather assumes a constant saving rate. This framework does not fit well with the remainderof the book, which is built around intertemporal optimization. Nevertheless, the Solow modeldelivers many important insights about both the long run trends of an economy and thesizeable cross-country differences in economic outcomes. Chapter 4 lays out some basicfacts about economic growth based on the contribution of Kaldor (1957). Chapter 5 studiesthe textbook Solow model. Chapter 6 considers an augmented version of the Solow modelwith exogenous productivity and population growth. Chapter 7 uses the Solow model toseek to understand cross-country differences in income. In the most recent edition of thebook, we have also included a chapter using a dynamic, optimizing, overlapping generationsframework (Chapter 8). While touching on similar issues to the Solow model, it allows todiscuss things like market efficiency and potentially beneficial roles of a government. Thoughit ends up having similar implications as the Solow model, because the OLG economy featuresoptimizing households in the context of a growth model, it provides a nice bridge to laterparts of the book.Part III is called the “Microeconomics of Macroeconomics” and studies optimal decisionmaking in a two period, intertemporal framework. This is the most math-heavy componentof the book, and later parts of the book, while referencing the material from this part, aremeant to be self-contained. Chapter 9 studies optimal consumption-saving decisions in atwo period framework, making use of indifference curves and budget lines. It also considersseveral extensions to the two period framework, including a study of the roles of wealth,uncertainty, and liquidity constraints in consumption-saving decisions. Chapter 10 extendsthis framework to more than two periods. Chapter 11 introduces the concept of competitiveequilibrium in the context of the two period consumption-saving framework, emphasizing thatthe real interest rate is an intertemporal price which adjusts to clear markets in equilibrium.It also includes some discussion on heterogeneity and risk-sharing, which motivates the useof the representative agent framework used throughout the book. Chapter 12 introducesproduction, and studies optimal labor and investment demand for a firm and optimal laborsupply for a household. Chapter 13 introduces fiscal policy into this framework. Here wediscuss Ricardian Equivalence, which is used later in the book, but also note the conditionsunder which Ricardian Equivalence will fail to hold. Chapter 14 introduces money intothe framework, motivating the demand for money through a money in the utility function5

assumption. Here we do not go into detail on the money creation process, instead reservingthat material for later in the book (Chapter 31). Chapter 15 discusses the equivalence of thedynamic production economy model laid out in Chapter 12 to the solution to a social planner’sproblem under certain conditions. In the process we discuss the First Welfare Theorem.Although we are mostly silent on unemployment, Chapter 16 includes a microeconomicallyfounded discussion of unemployment using the Diamond-Mortensen-Pissarides framework.The medium run is studied in Part IV. We refer to our model for understanding the mediumrun as the neoclassical model. It is based on the intertemporal frictionless production economystudied in more depth in Chapter 12, though the material is presented in such a way as to beself-contained. Most of the analysis is graphical in nature. The consumption, investment,money, and labor demand schedules used in this part come from the microeconomic decisionmaking problems studied in Part III, as does the labor supply schedule. Chapter 17 discussesthese decision rules and presents a graphical depiction of the equilibrium, which is based on atraditional IS curve summarizing the demand side and a vertical curve which we will the Y scurve (after Williamson 2014) to describe the supply-side. The Y s curve is vertical, ratherthan upward-sloping in a graph with the real interest rate on the vertical axis and output onthe horizontal, because of our assumption of no wealth effects on labor supply. AppendixC carries out the analysis where the Y s curve is instead upward-sloping, as in Williamson(2014). Chapter 18 graphically works through the effects of changes in exogenous variables onthe endogenous variables of the model. Chapter 19 presents some basic facts about observedbusiness cycle fluctuations and assesses the extent to which the neoclassical model can providea reasonable account of those facts. In Chapter 20 we study the connection between themoney supply, inflation, and nominal interest rates in the context of the neoclassical model.Chapter 21 discusses the policy implications of the model. The equilibrium is efficient, andso there is no scope for policy to attempt to combat fluctuations with monetary or fiscalinterventions. In this chapter we also include an extensive discussion of criticisms which havebeen levied at the neoclassical / real business cycle paradigm for thinking about economicpolicy. Chapter 22 considers an open economy version of the neoclassical model, studyingnet exports and exchange rates.Part V studies a New Keynesian model. This model is identical to the neoclassicalmodel, with the exception that the aggregate price level is sticky. This stickiness allowsdemand shocks to matter and means that money is non-neutral. It also means that the shortrun equilibrium is in general inefficient, opening the door for desirable policy interventions.Chapter 23 develops the IS-LM-AD curves to describe the demand side of the model. Whatdifferentiates the New Keynesian model from the neoclassical model is not the demand side,but rather the supply side. Hence, the IS-LM-AD curves can also be used to describe the6

demand side of the neoclassical model. We prefer our approach of first starting with the IS-Y scurves because it better highlights monetary neutrality and the classical dichotomy. Chapter24 develops a theory of a non-vertical aggregate supply curve based on price stickiness.An appendix develops a New Keynesian model based on wage stickiness rather than pricestickiness, Appendix D. Chapter 25 works out the effects of changes in exogenous variableson the endogenous variables of the New Keynesian model and compares those effects tothe neoclassical model. Chapter 26 develops a theory of the transition from short run tomedium run. In particular, if the short run equilibrium differs from what would obtainin the neoclassical model, over time pressure on the price level results in shifts of the ASrelationship that eventually restore the neoclassical equilibrium. On this basis we providetheoretical support for empirically observed Phillips Curve relationships. In Chapter 27 westudy optimal monetary policy in the Keynesian model. The optimal policy is to adjust themon

Intermediate Macroeconomics Julio Gar n Claremont McKenna College Robert Lester Colby College Eric Sims University of Notre Dame August 2, 2018 This Version: 3.0.0. This is a book designed for use in an intermediate macroeconomics course or a masters level course in macroeconomics. It could also be used by graduate students seeking a refresher

Related Documents:

MassBay EC 201 Principles of Macroeconomics 3 -- Bridgewater ECON 102 Principles of Macroeconomics 3 MassBay EC 201 Principles of Macroeconomics 3 -- Fitchburg ECON 1100 Principles of Economics: Macroeconomics 3 MassBay EC 201 Principles of Macroeconomics 3 -- Framingham ECON 101 Principles of Macroeconomics 3

36) Macroeconomics differs from microeconomics in that A) macroeconomics studies the decisions of individuals. B) microeconomics looks at the economy as a whole. C) macroeconomics studies the behavior of government while microeconomics looks at private corporations. D) macroeconomics focuses on the national economy and the global economy. Answer: D

Intermediate Macroeconomics Winter 2016 0.50 Credit weight General Course Information . (Blanchard, Johnson, 6th U.S. edition, Chapter 10) (Macroeconomics, Williamson S, . Olivier Blanchard and David R. Johnson Hardcover: 624 pages Publisher: Prentice Hall; 6th US edition (July 29th, .

The Macroeconomics of the Great Depression: A Comparative Approach BEN S. BERNANKE To UNDERSTAND THE GREAT DEPRESSION is the Holy Grail of macroeconomics. Not only did the Depression give birth to macroeconomics as a distinct field of study, but also—to an extent that is not always fully appreciated— the experience of the 1930s continues to influence macroeconomists' beliefs, policy .

Macroeconomics 3 Pre 1940. A period of exploration, where macroeconomics was not macroeconomics yet, but monetary theory on one side, business cycle theory on the other. A period during which all the right ingredients, and quite a few more, were developed. But also a period where con-fusion reigned, because of the lack of an integrated framework.

INTRODUCTION TO MACROECONOMICS COURSE DESCRIPTION There are two major branches in economics: ¾ Microeconomics ¾ Macroeconomics . OUTLINE OF THIS COURSE Introduction – Scope of Macroeconomics – Macroeconomic data and its me

most of the attention of students of macroeconomics. These matters are the topics to be examined this course (ECN202), Introductory Macroeconomics. Macroeconomics is a course that interfaces with several other academic disciplines. A significant amount of the material covered in this cours

Although there are different types of reports, in general, an academic report is a piece of informative writing, an act of communication and an account of an investigation (Reid, 2012). An academic report aims to sell a product, idea or points of view (Van Emden and Easteal, 1995). It should inform, explain and persuade (Williams, 1995) by using well- organised research. Sometimes it will .