A Review Of Merger Decisions In The EU: What Can We Learn From Ex-post .

1y ago
8 Views
2 Downloads
1.93 MB
113 Pages
Last View : 13d ago
Last Download : 3m ago
Upload by : Mollie Blount
Transcription

A review ofmerger decisions inthe EU:What can we learnfrom ex-postevaluations?Competition

EUROPEAN COMMISSIONDirectorate-General for CompetitionE-mail: comp-publications@ec.europa.euEuropean CommissionB-1049 Brussels

European CommissionA review of merger decisions in the EU: What can we learnfrom ex-post evaluations?Report by Peter Ormosi, Franco Mariuzzo, and Richard Havellwith Amelia Fletcher, Bruce LyonsJuly, 2015Luxembourg, 2015

Peter Ormosi, Franco Mariuzzo, Richard Havell, Amelia Fletcher, Bruce LyonsThe views and opinions expressed in this report are those of the authors, not of the EuropeanCommission.More information on the European Union is available on the Internet: http://europa.euMore information about Competition Policy is available on: http://ec.europa.eu/competitionLuxembourg: Publications Office of the European Union, 2015 European Union, 2015Reproduction is authorised provided the source is acknowledged.ISBN 978-92-79-51935-2doi: 10.2763/84342

Table of Contents1Introduction . 11.121.1.1Price effect estimating studies . 41.1.2Non-price effect and qualitative studies . 41.1.3Potential Biases . 5Estimating the price impact of mergers . 62.1Description of studies in the sample . 62.2Price effect of the transactions . 82.3Price effects and competition authority actions . 112.4Examining heterogeneity across merger studies . 132.4.1Market structure . 132.4.2The timing of the study . 142.4.3The relevant industry . 152.53Sample Description . 3Why are there fewer DiD studies in the EU? . 16Methodologies used in merger retrospectives . 183.1Difference-in-differences (DiD) . 183.1.1Assumptions needed for DiD . 193.1.1.1Parallel trends . 193.1.1.2No serial correlation . 203.1.1.3Exogenous mergers . 213.1.1.4No spill-over effects . 223.1.1.5Treatment and Control are sufficiently similar . 223.1.1.6Grouped error terms . 223.1.2Choice of control . 223.1.2.1Competitors’ prices . 233.1.2.2Local markets . 243.1.3The dataset . 253.1.3.1Sources of data . 253.1.3.2The time-range of data . 253.1.4What variables to control for . 263.1.5Robustness checks . 263.2Merger Simulation (MS) . 283.2.1Three steps of Merger Simulations . 283.2.2Types of merger simulations . 293.2.3Assumptions used in merger simulations . 303.2.4Data used in MS . 323.2.5Robustness checks and sensitivity analysis in MS models . 32

3.3Choosing between DiD and MS . 333.3.14Estimating with both DiD and MS . 33How to evaluate ex-post assessments . 364.14.1.1Identifying a potential error using DiD methods . 374.1.2Identifying a potential error using merger simulations . 404.2Is a potential error really an error by the CA? . 434.2.1Erroneous analysis . 434.2.2Other merger impacts dominate . 434.2.3Faulty evidence . 444.2.4Random variation. 444.2.5Small price increase . 454.35Does the ex-post assessment reveal a potential error in the CAs decision? . 36Which cases are more likely to attract error . 46Non-quantitative evaluations of the effect of mergers. 495.1Methodologies used in sample studies . 495.1.1Interviews. 505.1.2Quantitative techniques . 515.2Post-merger prices . 525.2.15.3Consumer welfare . 53Market structure . 545.3.1Market share of the merged firm. 555.3.2Concentration . 555.3.3Market size . 565.3.4Rivalry (coordinated behaviour) . 575.4Dynamic effects . 585.4.1Innovation . 595.4.2Capacity/Investment . 605.4.3Entry . 615.4.4Exit . 625.4.5Further mergers . 635.5Other effects . 645.5.1Buyer power. 645.5.2Imports . 655.5.3Service quality. 655.6Concluding thoughts on qualitative studies . 666Conclusion . 677References . 68Appendix. 73A1.Tables . 73A1.1. Price-effect studies . 73

A1.2. List of non-price studies . 83A2.Technical Appendix . 90A2.1. Difference-in-Differences . 90A2.1.1.Causal analysis . 90A2.1.2.Specific issues to complement discussion on Difference-in-Differences . 92A2.2. Merger simulations . 94A2.2.1.Deriving the demand function. 95A2.2.2.Demand specifications . 96A2.2.3.Inferring the marginal cost . 98A2.2.4.Simulating the merger (a hypothetical example) . 99

List of tablesTable 1: List of mergers included in this study (ordered by jurisdiction) . 6Table 2: Describing the sample . 7Table 3: Market structure in the sample mergers . 8Table 4: Mean price effects by direction of price change and type of study . 9Table 5: Kwoka’s price estimates broken down by the sign of price-change . 10Table 6: Mean price effects (%) by competition authority intervention and type of study. 11Table 7: Kwoka’s estimates broken down by decision type . 11Table 8: Direction of price change by CA intervention type . 12Table 9: The estimated price-effect of mergers by market concentration . 13Table 10: The estimated price-effect of the merger by the year of the price estimate . 15Table 11: Price effect by industry . 15Table 12: Number of mergers studied using DiD in the US and in Europe (by industry) 16Table 13: The direction of price change by choice of Control . 23Table 14: Identifying potential errors using DiD . 39Table 15 : Identifying potential errors using MS . 42Table 16: Sample means broken down by CA error . 46Table 17: Number of cases with/without error . 47Table 18: Sample means broken down by CA error ( 1% price change assumed as zero). 48Table 19: Non-quantitative assessments of price effects . 52Table 20: Post-merger price change by the timing of the study . 53Table 21: Qualitative evidence on the effect of mergers on market structure . 54Table 22: The effect of the merger on market shares (by the timing of the study) . 55Table 23: The effect of the merger on concentration (by the timing of the study) . 56Table 24: Qualitative evidence on dynamic effects of mergers . 59Table 25: The relationship between entry and market shares . 62Table 26: Qualitative evidence on other effects of mergers . 64Table 27: List of price-effect studies . 73Table 28: Market Structure in price-effect studies . 76Table 29: Data used in price-effect studies . 78Table 30: Estimation methods in price-effect studies . 80Table 31: List of non-price effect studies . 83Table 32: Effect on market structure (non-price studies) . 85Table 33: Dynamic effects (non-price studies) . 87Table 34: Other merger effects (non-price studies) . 89

Executive summaryDG COMP of the European Commission commissioned a team of academics (lead by PeterOrmosi) at the Centre for Competition Policy, University of East Anglia, to deliver a report,which systematically reviews ex-post evaluations of the impact of merger decisions by EUcompetition authorities. Ex-post merger evaluations (or merger retrospectives) estimatethe impact (typically on price) of mergers by using different econometric techniques. Theobjective of this report was to review the relevant literature of these mergerretrospectives, to discuss what the findings of these studies may imply about the qualityof merger decisions, introduce the relevant methodologies, and provide a framework foridentifying errors in merger decisions.The price effect of mergers(1)Given the size of the study sample and the likely non-random nature of selecting themergers to be evaluated, the findings of this study should be treated with caution asany conclusions drawn from this study are specific to the analysed sample.An important limitation of this report is that the sample of relevant merger retrospectivesis small and the mergers they evaluate are unlikely to be representative of the populationof mergers (we looked at 27 price-effect estimating studies and 50 studies evaluatingeffects other than price). For this reason we cannot generalise the findings of this reportand extrapolate them to the population of all merger decisions. Nevertheless, this exerciseis still useful as it allows an in-depth analysis of available studies and their findings. Thiscan reveal to us where potential weaknesses of merger decisions lie, and also identify ifmerger retrospectives – in their current form – can contribute to the process of mergercontrol, or whether they also need readjustment to better inform policy. In contrast to thewide use of merger retrospectives in the US the relative scarcity of similar studies in theEU is even more striking. Knowing how much these works could contribute to theoptimisation of merger decisions, EU competition authorities should be given the rightincentives to engage in such exercise on a more regular basis.(2)On average, mergers in our sample were followed by a price increase, although thisremained under 5 per cent in the large majority of cases. The average price increasein unconditionally approved mergers was just under 5 per cent and in remediedmergers between 1 and 2 per cent. In half of the unconditionally approved cases postmerger prices increased. The majority of remedied mergers are associated with aprice increase despite the remedy, although this increase is very small.Post-merger prices increased in around 60 per cent of the analysed sample. The priceincrease was worse (5%) in unconditionally approved mergers. This finding is similar to alarge study conducted on US ex-post merger studies (which also found that unconditionallyremedied mergers are followed by around 7% price increase). One the other hand,remedied mergers were followed by a very small price increase (around 1%), which is incontrast to the findings of the US study, which found that remedies have been largelyineffective in preventing a price-increase. Nevertheless, we caution against makingambitious comparisons between the two studies as it is likely that the two samples containvery different cases (probably due to different sample selection mechanisms).Where a price increase follows an unconditionally approved merger, it seems tempting tojump to the conclusion that the competition authority ‘made an error’. Similarly, a priceincrease following a remedied merger would suggest that the authority was right inimposing a remedy, but the remedy did not fully eliminate the price-increase. When furtherinvestigating the price-increase cases, we point out that some of these are likely torepresent a genuine error in the decision, and others are possibly a result of other factors(non-price effects were given priority over price effects, faulty evidence, or random error).(3)Average estimates of post-merger price increase were around zero where the marketwas less concentrated. In more concentrated markets the average estimated pricei

increase was large (between 10% and 20%), but only if the merger had beenunconditionally approved. In the sample, remedies had been able to reduce postmerger price-increases even in concentrated markets.Market structure is still very much in the focus of merger control as an indicator of thelikely market power increasing effect of the merger. For this reason we collectedinformation on three different measures of market concentration (number of firms, marketshare of the largest merging firm, and HHI). We found that market concentration is astrong driver of the estimated price-effect of the merger. The average price increase inmarkets that are considered un-concentrated based on conventional measures ofconcentration is around zero. In concentrated markets, on the other hand, the averageprice increase is large, although the remedies managed to mitigate the post-merger pricehike even in concentrated markets.The methodology used(4)In Difference-in-Differences studies the change in the price of the merging firms(Treatment) is compared with the change in the price of a counterfactual market(Control). The following assumptions have to be satisfied: the prices in the Controland Treatment markets follow a parallel trend; price at one period is not correlatedwith price at another period; firms’ decision to merge is not correlated withunobserved characteristics that also affect the relevant prices; prices in the Controlgroup are not affected by the merger; and there is sufficient similarity between theTreatment and the Control markets.Difference-in-Differences methods (18 studies in our sample) are the most frequently usedtool for evaluating the impact of individual merger decisions. It compares how the pricesin the merger market (Treatment) change, with how prices change in a sufficiently similarmarket (Control). This is based on the assumption that the Control market is what themerger market would have been in the absence of the merger. Of course, for the methodto provide unbiased estimates, certain assumptions have to hold. One key contribution ofthis report is that it catalogues these assumptions and explain them in the context ofevaluating merger decisions. It highlights the possible biases in estimates that violatethese assumptions. Therefore the methodological discussion in this report also serves asa short reference guide for conducting merger ex-post evaluations.(5)In Difference-in-Differences studies the Control group is typically composed of rivalfirms or local markets not affected by the merger. The selection of the Control groupshould follow a formalised procedure, ensuring that the Control is sufficiently similarto the Treatment (the merger market), and that there are no spill-over effects. Thepossibility of spill-over effects (the merger affecting competitors’ prices) is more likelyto be an issue where rivals are used as Control.One key condition of reliable price-change estimates is that the Control group (the groupagainst whom the merger prices are compared) is selected in a way that best satisfies theassumptions above (sufficiently similar to the Treatment group but not affected by themerger). There are formal procedures for selecting the best Control group, such aspropensity score matching and iterative techniques such as those adopted in Chone et al(2012), and these are discussed in sufficient detail in this report.(6)In Difference-in-Differences studies, if available, the data should span over longer thana year following the merger in order to allow any market self-correction to take place.In our sample we found that a third of the studies looked at price effects within a yearafter the merger.The time-span of the data used for assessing the impact of a merger is a surprisinglyunder-discussed part of merger retrospectives. This report argues that sufficiently longtime has to be allowed to pass after the merger, before the impact evaluations can bedone. The rationale is simple. It is possible that the immediate price-shock, caused by themerger, is self-corrected by the market within few years following the merger. It is alsoii

possible that in the immediate aftermath of the merger prices increase only in marketsdirectly affected by the merger, but then the effect spreads on to other markets later on.Both of these possibilities have to be accounted for when designing an ex-post study. Itseems unlikely that a competition authority would choose to intervene if it believed thatmarket self-correction would offset the price increase within one or two years after themerger. It is also unlikely that the competition authority would refrain from intervention ifit judged that the anti-competitive effects of the merger might take a few years to fullydevelop. For these reasons it is vital that the ex-post study uses data that spans sufficientlyfar following the consummation of the merger. On the other hand, longer spanning datais more likely to contain confounding effects (i.e. effects other than the merger). The bestpractice appears to be to estimate the effect of the merger in each subsequent yearfollowing the merger.(7)Merger simulations can be done using ex-ante or ex-post data. The former can informus how far the competition authority’s decision fell from the best possible prediction (afull-fledged merger simulation). The latter can tell us how the merger affected themarket, whilst accounting for various post-merger market developments. The dataused in this exercise should include: (1) post-merger price, market share and productcharacteristics to estimate own-, and cross-price elasticities in the post-mergerequilibrium; (2) marginal costs and information on efficiency gains; and (3) howmarket structure evolved post-merger through entry and exit. If both ex-ante and expost data are available and have similar length, then the research can test if demandcharacteristics change with the merger.Merger Simulations (9 studies in our sample) are a widely used method for predicting theeffects of the merger during the competition authority’s investigation. This report arguesand demonstrates that they can also be used for the ex post assessment of mergerdecisions. If the simulation uses data that was already available during the investigation(ex-ante data) then the findings of the simulation can show us how far the authority’smerger decision fell from the best possible prediction (this is based on the assumption thata full-fledged simulation would provide the best prediction pre-merger). If the simulationuses data from after the merger, then it can work as a genuine ex-post evaluation tool.Merger Simulations have another important characteristic: unless accounting for efficiencygains they always estimate a post-merger price increase – simply because the simulationcompares two scenarios, one with n number of firms (pre-merger), and the other one withn–1 firms (post-merger). For this reason it is vital to incorporate efficiency gains in themodel and, possibly, entry of new products or firms.(8)If possible, the ex-post assessment of merger decisions should use both Difference-inDifferences and Merger Simulation to learn from the comparison between the twomethods.Although this is very demanding task, given the amount of complementarity betweenDifference-in-Differences and Merger Simulation estimates, the two estimates togethercould give a more complete picture of the effect of mergers. Difference-in-Differencesestimates reveal what happens to measurable factors such as post-merger price, on theother hand Merger Simulation can estimate the effect of unobserved scenarios(counterfactuals), such as alternative merger remedies or a non-remedied merger, orblocked mergers, and it can also provide welfare estimations.How to evaluate the merger decision?(9)Because of its relative simplicity the Difference-in-Differences method is typicallypreferred to Merger Simulations for analysing approved mergers with no intervention.On the other hand, Difference-in-Differences methods are less suitable for detecting ifthe competition authority made an unnecessary intervention (Type I error). Ex-postMerger Simulations are capable of fully identifying decision errors in the mergerintervention (remedy or block) provided that efficiency gains are incorporated in theiii

simulations. Merger simulations are also able to estimate the welfare impact ofmergers.The report provides a framework for evaluating the competition authority’s mergerdecision. It distinguishes between two type of errors: (1) where the authority made anunnecessary intervention (Type I error), and (2) where the authority’s intervention wasnot sufficient (Type II error). In general, because of its simplicity, the Difference-inDifferences method is preferred if the merger was unconditionally approved. However,because it always compares the merger price with the non-merger price, it is more limitedin its assessment of whether a Type I error was made in a remedied or blocked mergerdecision. To give an example: a price drop or no price change after a remedied mergerwould imply that there was no Type II error (the intervention was not deficient). However,without knowing what would have happened under an un-remedied merger (or under aless intervening remedy) we cannot tell if there was a Type I error. It is possible that themerger would have led to a price drop even without the remedy – in which case it was anerror to intervene (Type I error). It is also possible that the un-remedied merger wouldhave pushed up prices and the remedy eliminated this threat (No error). For the samereason, using Difference-in-Difference methods are less able to identify whether thecompetition authority made an error in the design of the remedy. Merger Simulations arepreferred in these cases.(10)In more than half of the analysed sample, prices increased after the competitionauthority’s intervention. A post-merger price increase may not imply an erroneousmerger decision: (1) if non-price effects dominated price effects and the authorityrecognised this, (2) if the decision was based on faulty facts, or (3) if the post-mergerprice increase could have been seen as random variation at the time of the authority’sdecision.A central message of this report is that an estimate that shows increased post-mergerprices does not necessarily mean that the competition authority had made an error. To beable to assess whether there was an error one has interpret the findings of the study inthe context of the authority’s decision. The only time that we can conclude that thedecision was erroneous is when the authority had all information at hand that should haveenabled it to predict the price increase, but despite this it made an erroneous assessmentleading up to a decision that did not stop the negative effects of the merger. On the otherhand, if effects – other than price – inspired the authority’s decision then even if theauthority had perfectly foreseen a small price increase, these could have been toleratedfor the sake of non-price effects. Similarly, it is possible that a small price increase wouldhave appeared as a random error at the time of the decision. It is also likely in manyinstances that authorities would not intervene a merger with a very small price increase,if it can be reasonably expected to be self-corrected by the market.(11)The competition authority was more likely to have made a decision error in moreconcentrated markets.The study also looked at the observable characteristics of cases where there was apotential error in the merger decision. We found that potential errors were more likely inconcentrated markets. This seems to imply, that CAs should pay more attention to highlyconcentrated markets, which is in line with current thinking as expressed in the EuropeanCommission's guidelines.The non-price effect of mergers(12)Looking at how market structure changed post-merger may provide useful informationfor assessing the competition authority’s decision. Developments in the joint marketshare of the merging firms, the level of rivalry, the level of concentration, and the sizeof the market are all informative for this purpose. We found that there is a non-trivialnumber of cases where the merger was followed by higher concentration, less rivalry,or l

which systematically reviews ex-post evaluations of the impact of merger decisions by EU competition authorities. Ex-post merger evaluations (or merger retrospectives) estimate . of merger decisions, introduce the relevant methodologies, and provide a framework for identifying errors in merger decisions.

Related Documents:

Impact Evaluation of Merger Decisions (2011) Economic Evidence in Merger Analysis (2011) Remedies in Merger Cases . Cross-Border Merger Cases held by the Competition Committee (Working Party No. 3 on Co-operation and Enforcement) in October 2013.

The evaluation of competitive merger e ects is an important topic for rm managers and an- . In this case, the merger impact is heterogeneous across merging rms and the response parameter of interest is correlated with the merger variable, such that the . Firms make their decisions whether to merger or not in anticipation of the expected .

The evaluation of the economic effects of bureaucratic or legal institutions' decisions is both . analyzing merger control decisions, for example, there is uncertainty about the merger effects per se, the impact of the antitrust authority's decision, and the perennial problem of the proper . CAAR around the merger's announcement .

The evaluation of the economic effects of bureaucratic or legal institutions' decisions is both . analyzing merger control decisions, for example, there is uncertainty about the merger effects per se, the impact of the antitrust authority's decision, and the perennial problem of the proper . CAAR around the merger's announcement .

Merger Decision's Correctness Based on a LEAR study on ex-post merger evaluation for the UK Competition Commission (CC) - link We analyze the merger among two major book resellers in the UK Waterstone's and Ottakar's (Aguzzoni et al., 2013) It was cleared by the UK CC in 2006 We look at the price effect of the merger at different levels (local and

approach for assessing the validity of merger decisions by applying it to a setting where the limitations of this approach are not very severe. 7 In particular, as Friberg and Romahn (2012) point out, one challenge in the application of such methodology is the difficulty of properly identifying a before-merger period and an after-merger period.

In doing so, we propose an ex-post evaluation of this merger. During the period studied (2011 to 2016), the fuel price dropped by almost two-thirds, causing a drop in the marginal . The merger and the entry/exit decisions of both the new . to simulate the merger impact (see, among others, Berry and Pakes, 1993; Nevo, 2001; Peters, .

API RP 500 and API RP 505 NFPA 497 and NFPA 499. PETRONAS Technical Standards provides guidelines to ensure proper management of Ex Equipment. 1. Ex Electrical Equipment Inspection and Maintenance Guidelines (Ex IMG) Standards and Guidelines Personnel Inspection Maintenance 2. Ex Equipment Repair Guidelines (Ex ERG) 3. Ex Management Assessment Guidelines (Ex MAG) 4. Ex .