14 Redistribution, Inequality, And Growth

3y ago
5 Views
2 Downloads
1.34 MB
30 Pages
Last View : 1m ago
Last Download : 3m ago
Upload by : Shaun Edmunds
Transcription

Jonathan D. Ostry, Andrew Berg, and Charalambos G. TsangaridesSDN/14/XSDN/14/02XXRedistribution, Inequality,and GrowthFebruary 2014I M F S T A F F D I1 S C U S S I O N N O T E

INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUNDResearch DepartmentRedistribution, Inequality, and GrowthPrepared by Jonathan D. Ostry, Andrew Berg, Charalambos G. Tsangarides1Authorized for distribution by Olivier BlanchardApril 2014DISCLAIMER: This Staff Discussion Note represents the views of the authors anddoes not necessarily represent IMF views or IMF policy. The views expressed hereinshould be attributed to the authors and not to the IMF, its Executive Board, or itsmanagement. Staff Discussion Notes are published to elicit comments and to furtherdebate.1JEL Classification Numbers:O11, O15, O47, E62, H23Keywords:Redistribution, Inequality, GrowthAuthor’s E-mail Address:JOstry@imf.org; ABerg@imf.org; CTsangarides@imf.orgWe thank Olivier Blanchard and numerous IMF colleagues for useful comments, Frederick Solt for help with thedata, Yorbol Yakhshilikov for superb research support, and Anne Lalramnghakhleli Moses for assistance.

3Editor’s Note: This is a revised version of SDN/14/02 as posted in February 2014, toinclude an online data appendix, and to correct a few issues with the data and statisticalprocedures, none of which is consequential for the results. The resulting changes are toTables 2, 3, and 4; Figures 6 and 8; and the associated text on pages 17, 18, and 24.CONTENTSPAGEExecutive Summary . 4I. Introduction . 5II. A Review of the Literature on Equality, Redistribution and Growth . 7III. Inequality and Redistribution: Some Facts . 11IV. Inequality, Redistribution, and Growth: Empirical Results . 15A. Medium-term growth. 17B. Growth spell duration . 21V. Conclusion . 25References 27TABLES1. Correlation Between Redistribution and Transfers . 132. Correlation Between Market Inequality and Redistribution . 153. The Effect of Inequality and Redistribution on Growth . 184. Alternative Samples: Inequality, Redistribution, and Growth . 205. The Effect of Inequality and Redistribution on the Duration of Growth Spells . 226. Alternative Samples: Inequality, Redistribution, and the Duration of Growth Spells . 25FIGURES1. Interrelationships Between Inequality, Redistribution, and Growth . 92. Evolution of Market and Net Inequality, 1960–2010. 143. Market and Net Inequality by Country Group . 144. Growth, Inequality, and Redistribution . . 165. Duration of Growth Spells, Inequality, and Redistribution. 166. The Effect of Inequality and Redistribution on Growth . 197. Redistribution: The Top 25 Percent and the Bottom 75 Percent . 238. The Effect of Inequality and Redistribution on Growth Spell Duration . 24

4EXECUTIVE SUMMARYEconomists are increasingly focusing on the links between rising inequality and the fragility ofgrowth. Narratives include the relationship between inequality, leverage and the financialcycle, which sowed the seeds for crisis; and the role of political-economy factors (especiallythe influence of the rich) in allowing financial excess to balloon ahead of the crisis. In earlierwork, we documented a multi-decade cross-country relationship between inequality and thefragility of economic growth. Our work built on the tentative consensus in the literature thatinequality can undermine progress in health and education, cause investment-reducing politicaland economic instability, and undercut the social consensus required to adjust in the face ofshocks, and thus that it tends to reduce the pace and durability of growth.That equality seems to drive higher and more sustainable growth does not in itself supportefforts to redistribute. In particular, inequality may impede growth at least in part because itcalls forth efforts to redistribute that themselves undercut growth. In such a situation, even ifinequality is bad for growth, taxes and transfers may be precisely the wrong remedy.While considerable controversy surrounds these issues, we should not jump to the conclusionthat the treatment for inequality may be worse for growth than the disease itself. Equalityenhancing interventions could actually help growth: think of taxes on activities with negativeexternalities paid mostly by the rich (perhaps excessive risk-taking in the financial sector) orcash transfers aimed at encouraging better attendance at primary schools in developingcountries, as examples. The macroeconomic effects of redistributive policies will reflect abalance between the components of the fiscal package, and it is an empirical question whetherredistribution in practice is pro- or anti-growth.So what does the historical evidence say? This paper is the first to take advantage of a recentlycompiled cross-country dataset that distinguishes market (before taxes and transfers) inequalityfrom net (after taxes and transfers) inequality and allows us to calculate redistributive transfersfor a large number of country-year observations. Our main findings are:First, more unequal societies tend to redistribute more. It is thus important in understandingthe growth-inequality relationship to distinguish between market and net inequality.Second, lower net inequality is robustly correlated with faster and more durable growth, for agiven level of redistribution. These results are highly supportive of our earlier work.And third, redistribution appears generally benign in terms of its impact on growth; only inextreme cases is there some evidence that it may have direct negative effects on growth. Thusthe combined direct and indirect effects of redistribution—including the growth effects of theresulting lower inequality—are on average pro-growth.While we should be cognizant of the inherent limitations of the data set and of cross-countryregression analysis more generally, we should be careful not to assume that there is a big tradeoff between redistribution and growth. The best available macroeconomic data do not supportthat conclusion.

5I. INTRODUCTIONEconomists are increasingly focusing on the links between rising inequality, crisis risk, andsustainable growth. Rajan (2010) underscores how inequality intensified the leverage andfinancial cycle, sowing the seeds of crisis, while Stiglitz (2012) stresses the role of politicaleconomy factors (especially the influence of the rich) in allowing financial excess to balloonahead of the crisis. Berg and Ostry (2011) document the multi-decade and multi-countryevidence that greater equality can help sustain growth. This work builds on a tentativeconsensus in the growth literature that inequality can undermine progress in health andeducation, cause investment-reducing political and economic instability, and undercut thesocial consensus required to adjust in the face of major shocks, and thus that it tends to reducethe pace and durability of growth (Persson and Tabellini, 1994; Easterly, 2007; Berg, Ostry andZettelmeyer, 2012).2That equality seems to drive higher and more sustainable growth does not, in itself, supportefforts to redistribute. In particular, inequality may impede growth at least in part because itcalls forth efforts to redistribute through the fiscal system, efforts that themselves mayundermine growth. In such a situation, even if inequality is bad for growth, taxes and transfersmay be precisely the wrong remedy. While the literature on this score remains controversial,the notion of a tradeoff between redistribution and growth seems deeply embedded inpolicymakers’ consciousness. The negative effect of redistributive policies is indeed the centraltheme of Arthur Okun’s famous 1975 book on the tradeoffs between efficiency and equity andon the efficiency “leaks” that efforts to reduce inequality engender.We should not jump to the conclusion that a treatment for inequality—redistribution—may beworse for growth than the disease itself. First, we need to ask if equality-enhancinginterventions would invariably lead to a loss of economic efficiency, as Okun and othersassumed. On reflection, that is too broad-brush a conclusion: we are all familiar with win-winpolicies that have potential both to promote efficiency and equality. Examples could includetaxes on activities with negative externalities paid mostly by the better-off but harmful to thepoor (such as, perhaps, excessive risk-taking in the financial sector), cash transfers aimed atencouraging better attendance at primary schools in developing countries, or spending onpublic capital or education that benefits the poor. A number of papers (such as Benabou, 2000,2002; and Bleaney, Gemmell, and Kneller, 2001) point out that some categories of governmentspending—for example, public investments in infrastructure, spending on health and education,and social insurance provision—may be both pro-growth and pro-equality, while othercategories may imply the tradeoffs that preoccupied Okun. The macroeconomic effects ofredistributive policies are likely to reflect a balance between different components of the fiscal2Others go further—beyond the scope of this paper—and focus on the social and political consequences of risinginequality trends in advanced countries (for example, Reich, 2011; Wilkinson and Pickett, 2009).

6package, and it would appear to be an empirical question whether redistribution in practice ispro- or anti-growth.One useful way forward in the face of this uncertainty is to look carefully at the evidence aboutthe different specific elements of redistributive fiscal policies in different country contexts,attempting to draw lessons about the most efficient ways to redistribute. Here we tackle thebroader and complementary question head-on: what does the historical macroeconomicevidence say about the relationship between inequality, redistribution, and growth? Inparticular, can we find evidence that, on average, the negative growth effects of inequalityoutweigh any positive growth effects of the resulting reduction in inequality?To disentangle the various channels, we need a framework that simultaneously analyzes theeffects of redistributive transfers and inequality on growth. This is essential not only for anadequate econometric specification and a correct measurement of the different effects, but alsofor a sensible discussion of policy. One reason the literature has been slow to carry out thissimultaneous analysis is that it requires cross-country data on both inequality before taxes andtransfers (so-called “market inequality”) and inequality after taxes and transfers (“netinequality”). Such data are scarce and imperfect. This paper is the first to take advantage of arecently-compiled cross-country dataset (Solt, 2009) that carefully distinguishes net frommarket inequality and allows us to calculate redistributive transfers—defined as the differencebetween the Gini coefficient for market and for net inequality—for a large number of countryyear observations covering both advanced and developing countries.3We analyze both the growth rate over five-year horizons (panel growth regressions) and theduration of growth spells, as defined in Berg, Ostry, and Zettelmeyer (2012), which we think isa more useful way of assessing growth experience, especially for emerging and developingeconomies. Our principal findings can be summarized as follows.First, more unequal societies tend to redistribute more. Among OECD countries, moreinequality tends to be associated on average roughly one-for-one with higher redistribution,such that there is almost no overall correlation between net and market inequality. While theeffect is weaker in non-OECD countries, it is nevertheless still present. It is thus important todistinguish between market and net inequality in trying to understand the growth-inequalitynexus and to separately control for redistribution in growth-inequality work.Second, lower net inequality seems to drive faster and more durable growth for a given level ofredistribution. These results are highly supportive of our earlier work, now encompassing not3There have been many efforts in the literature to look at either market or net inequality, but Solt (2009) breaksnew ground in his efforts to make the various underlying survey data comparable across time and countries for alarge number of countries.

7only duration analysis but also the panel regression approach common in earlier literature, andalso controlling for the net/market distinction.Third, redistribution appears generally benign in its impact on growth; only in extreme casesis there some evidence that it may have direct negative effects on growth. Thus the combineddirect and indirect effects of redistribution—including the growth effects of the resulting lowerinequality—are, on average, pro-growth.Against these results, it must be borne in mind that the data are particularly scarce andunreliable for redistribution, even more so than for inequality. Indeed, one possibleinterpretation of our results is that the data on redistribution simply do not contain enoughinformation to infer a negative (or for that matter a positive) direct effect. We believe ourresults are nonetheless informative. We have used the best available data for the analysis oflarge numbers of countries over time. The analysis of spells inevitably requires the use of olderand perhaps less comparable data, but the results for average growth hold even when theanalysis is restricted to only the most reliable and recent data.We should of course be cautious about drawing definitive policy implications from crosscountry regression analysis. We know that different sorts of policies are likely to have differenteffects in different countries at different times, and causality is difficult to establish with fullconfidence. But microeconomic analyses, as useful as they are, leave one wondering: What isthe overall relationship? What can we learn from looking at the forest, not the trees? What wefind is that we should not assume that there is a big trade-off between redistribution andgrowth: the best available macro data do not support that conclusion.The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. In Section II, we set the stage byreviewing the literature on growth, inequality, and redistribution, and in the section followingthat we present the data being used to carry out the empirical analysis. In Section IV wepresent the panel growth regressions, while in Section V we discuss the duration analysis,linking sustainability of growth to equality, redistribution, and a range of traditionaldeterminants. A final section concludes.II. A REVIEW OF THE LITERATURE ON EQUALITY, REDISTRIBUTION, AND GROWTHA large literature has examined the three variables of interest in this paper, resulting in acomplex set of proposed relationships. Before surveying the evidence, it is worth spending amoment to understand the possible channels (summarized in Figure 1) and also to understandwhy theory does not provide strong guidance on these questions.Inequality can influence growth (line E in Figure 1) positively by providing incentives forinnovation and entrepreneurship (Lazear and Rosen, 1981); by raising saving and investment ifrich people save a higher fraction of their income (Kaldor, 1957); and, perhaps especially

8relevant for poor countries, by allowing at least a few individuals to accumulate the minimumneeded to start businesses and get a good education (Barro, 2000). But inequality may beharmful for growth because it deprives the poor of the ability to stay healthy and accumulatehuman capital (Perotti, 1996; Galor and Moav, 2004; Aghion, Caroli, and Garcia-Penalosa,1999); generates political and economic instability that reduces investment (Alesina andPerotti, 1996); and impedes the social consensus required to adjust to shocks and sustaingrowth (Rodrik, 1999). The relationship between inequality and growth may be nonlinear, as inthe theoretical model of Benhabib (2003), in which increases in inequality from low levelsprovides growth-enhancing incentives, while increases past some point encourage rent-seekingand lower growth.On the relationship between market inequality and redistribution (line A in Figure 1), weemphasize the channel underscored in the seminal paper of Meltzer and Richard (1981), whoargue that higher inequality will create pressures for redistribution. The notion is that, at leastin democracies, political power is more evenly distributed than economic power, so that amajority of voters will have the power and incentive to vote for redistribution. However, aspointed out by Benabou (2000) and emphasized by Stiglitz (2012), this need not be the case ifthe rich have more political influence than the poor.On the third issue, the policy literature has focused on the direct effect (line D in Figure 1) andgenerally assumed that redistribution hurts growth (Okun, 1975), as higher taxes and subsidiesdampen incentives to work and invest. Losses are likely to be a rising function of the tax orsubsidy rate, given the convexity of deadweight costs, with losses from redistribution minimalwhen tax rates are low but rising steeply with the tax or subsidy rate (for example, Barro, 1990;Jaimovich and Rebelo, 2012). But some have recognized that redistribution need not beinherently detrimental to growth, to the degree that it involves reducing tax expenditures orloopholes that benefit the rich or as part of broader tax reforms (such as higher inheritancetaxes offset by lower taxes on labor income). More broadly, redistribution can also occur whenprogressive taxes finance public investment, when social insurance spending enhances thewelfare of the poor and risk taking (Benabou, 2000), or when higher health and educationspending benefits the poor, helping to offset labor and capital market imperfections (Saint-Pauland Verdier, 1993, 1997). In such cases, redistributive policies could increase both equalityand growth. The literature has generally ignored the overall effects of redistribution, bothdirect effects (line D of Figure 1) and as it acts through inequality (lines C and E), becausevery few papers look at both inequality and redistribution simultaneously. We return to thisissue below.Clearly, theory provides at best a partial guide on these issues, and we need to turn to theevidence. With respect to inequality and growth, the statistical evidence generally supports theview that inequality impedes growth, at least over the medium term. In a sequence that mirrorsintellectual fashions on the empirics of growth, researchers have looked at rates of growth overlong periods of time (for example, Persson and Tabellini, 1996; Perotti, 1996; Alesina and

9Figure

INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND Research Department Redistribution, Inequality, and Growth Prepared by Jonathan D. Ostry, Andrew Berg, Charalambos G. Tsangarides1 Authorized for distribution by Olivier BlanchardFile Size: 1MB

Related Documents:

Income inequality has two components: (a) ‘market’ inequality and (b) govern-ment redistribution via taxes and transfers. In principle, the two can be combined in any of a variety of ways: low market inequality with high redistribution, low market inequality with low redistribution, high market inequality

increases and if it decreases in income inequality. If income distribution is Pareto, the rate of redistribution increases monotonically in income inequality if ˇ 0:78 and it has an internal maximum if . Moreover, the maximum occurs at a lower level of inequality, so that the rate of redistribution de

INEQUALITY, REDISTRIBUTION, AND RENT-SEEKING FRANCISCO RODRI GUEZ This paper presents a non-median voter model of redistribution in which greater inequality leads to lower redistribution. Bargaining between in-terest groups and politicians over exemptions implies that individuals with sufficiently high

inequality and growth or redistribution and growth can be found, while there is some in-dication for a positive relation between top income shares and growth. Berg et al. (2014) are using the preceding version of the SWIID in a study on redistribution, inequality and growth. The focus is on the impact of

inequality could negatively impact economic development, or income redistribution could positively impact economic development. Particular attention has been paid to the impor-tance of a redistribution policy that promotes human capital development. In terms of inequality and redistributio

that increasing income inequality has reached a level that is becoming a brake on growth. For this reason, there is no fundamental contradiction between state-led income redistribution and economic growth. The reduction of income inequality should not be limited to a pure redistribution

How Inequality Arises Income Redistribution 18.1 INEQUALITY IN THE UNITED STATES We measure economic inequality by looking at the distributions of income and wealth. A household’s income is the amount that

growth will be discussed. Concepts on both regional income inequality and local economic growth will follow. 2.1 Theories on Income Inequality: Does Harm Growth Stiglitz (2012) argues inequality slows economic growth. According to Stiglitz, inequality weakens aggregate demand f