Advertising And Portfolio Choice - CeRP

1y ago
9 Views
2 Downloads
730.17 KB
53 Pages
Last View : 1m ago
Last Download : 3m ago
Upload by : Braxton Mach
Transcription

Advertising and Portfolio Choice* Henrik Cronqvist** The Ohio State University Fisher College of Business Department of Finance This draft: 9/15/2005 Abstract Using a unique large-scale event, the year 2000 launch of a privatized social security system involving individual savings accounts in Sweden, I report empirical evidence on the link between fund advertising and people’s fund and portfolio choices. First, content analysis reveals that a very small portion of ads can be construed as directly informative about characteristics relevant for rational mutual fund investors, such as funds’ expense ratios. Second, higher levels of advertising expenditures do not appear to signal ex ante higher unobservable fund manager quality or talent. Third, fund advertising affects people’s portfolio choices, even when advertising does not appear to contain any information. Finally, fund advertising steers people to portfolios with lower returns and higher risk. My results have important implications for a welfare analysis of fund advertising and portfolio choices, asset pricing models, and mutual fund industry policy making, and may serve as a starting point for wider and more formal analysis of the effects of advertising, marketing, and persuasion in financial markets. JEL classification: G11; G18; G23; M37 Keywords: Portfolio choice; Individual investor behavior; Mutual funds; Advertising * This paper is my dissertation from The University of Chicago Graduate School of Business. I want to thank my committee members Nicholas Barberis, Anil Kashyap, Tobias Moskowitz, Per Strömberg, and Richard Thaler for their comments. I am deeply indebted to my chair, Richard Thaler, for his enthusiasm and for encouraging me to pursue research in this area. The suggestions by seminar participants at Boston College, Chicago GSB, CMU, Cornell, Emory, HBS, Michigan, Notre Dame, Ohio State University, UNC, and the joint University of Oregon and JFE Conference on Delegated Portfolio Management have been of significant help in revising an early draft. The comments by Eugene Fama, Richard Green, Milton Harris, David Hirshleifer, Roni Michaely, Wayne Mikkelson, Mattias Nilsson, Jeffrey Pontiff, Laura Starks and Frank Yu were particularly helpful. I acknowledge financial support from Dr. Marcus Wallenberg’s Foundation. Finally, I want to thank all the providers of data that have made this research possible, in particular the Premium Pension Authority, MarketWatch, and the National Library of Sweden. Any remaining errors are mine. ** E-mail address: henrik.cronqvist@cob.osu.edu.

1. Introduction Advertising is an increasingly important phenomenon in the mutual fund industry. More and more funds launch large campaigns, involving costly newspaper advertisements or television commercials. There is also anecdotal evidence that funds aggressively attempt to recruit “brand managers” from successful retail companies such as e.g. Taco Bell (e.g., Brandstrader (1996)). Statistics show that funds, in the U.S. alone, now spend more than 6 billion dollars on advertising annually, about ten times more than a decade ago. Despite the importance of advertising as a phenomenon in the mutual fund industry, financial economists have paid almost no attention to it. In this article, I fill this gap in the literature by asking the following question: does fund advertising affect people’s portfolio choices? The mere size and scope of the fund advertising phenomenon makes it interesting to study. There are however at least two other reasons why a study of fund advertising is important. First, there is a trend towards investor autonomy around the world. Many companies move away from defined benefits plans, and to defined contribution (DC) savings plans, like 401(k)-plans in the U.S. For example, Poterba, Venti and Wise (2001) report that about 85% of the private pension plan contributions in the U.S. are to plans in which retirement savers themselves choose how to invest their money. The trend towards investor autonomy is apparent also in the current world-wide debates over whether to privatize public pension systems, such as Social Security in the U.S. As more and more people are given the responsibility to act as their own money managers, an increasing number of them will be exposed to fund advertising when they elect investments in their retirement savings accounts. Second, there is also a trend towards an expansion in the number of investment alternatives available to retirement savers and other individual investors. For example, about a decade ago, investors in the world’s largest DC-plan had only two choices, a bond fund (TIAA) and a stock fund (CREF). Today, most plans offer more than one provider of funds and dozens, if not hundreds, of funds from which to choose. And in the U.S. mutual fund industry as a whole, 1

statistics from the Investment Company Institute show that people have 8,256 choices, i.e. there are more funds than stocks to pick from. Clearly, the potential role for fund advertising is much more significant today, when the number of investment alternatives is in the thousands, than when people had only a limited number of choices. So how then may fund advertising affect people’s portfolio choices? Economic theory and experimental evidence suggest several potential links between advertising and portfolio choices. First, advertising may provide direct information about characteristics of a product or brand that are relevant to a consumer. Fund advertising may for example provide information about the “price” of funds, i.e. fund fees. This would reduce the search costs in the mutual fund industry. Second, the level of “uninformative” may be used as a signal for the initially unobservable quality of a product. If managers with certain unobservable ability and talents are better than others, higher fund advertising expenditures may be used to signal higher quality. Finally, experimental evidence has shown that mere repeated exposure to a stimulus enhances people’s attitude towards it. Thus, mere exposure to an advertisement for a fund may enhance people’s attitude towards the advertising fund or fund complex, even if the advertisements provide no information at all. These hypotheses regarding a possible link between advertising and portfolio choice motivates the formal empirical work pursued in this paper. A serious obstacle constraining any empirical attempt to study whether fund advertising affects portfolio choices is the lack of data. It is very difficult to obtain detailed and comprehensive data on people’s portfolio choices as well as data on fund advertising. While extremely important in turning financial economists’ attention to fund advertising, the paper by Jain and Wu (2000) illustrates this problem: they use a very small sample (294 ads) and, as an explanatory variable, a dummy that is one if a fund had an ad in two specialized magazines 2

(Barron’s or Money magazine) during the period 1994-1996, and zero otherwise.1 I deal with the data availability problems by examining data generated by a unique event: the year 2000 launch of a privatized social security system involving individual savings accounts in Sweden. I combine two datasets in my analysis, one on people’s portfolio choices, and one on fund advertising. The dataset on people’s portfolio choices comes from the government authority that administrates the system, and consists of the portfolio choices for 4.4 million Swedish workers, in total allocating 5.6 billion dollars. The dataset on fund advertising comes from a Swedish marketing research company’s proprietary database, and contains detailed information on the advertising campaigns by the 455 participating mutual funds, in total 94.4 million dollars worth of ad expenditures, and close to 50,000 different fund advertisements and commercials. I report four main results. First, content analysis reveals that a very small portion of ads can be construed as directly informative about characteristics relevant for rational mutual fund investors, such as funds’ expense ratios. Second, higher levels of advertising expenditures do not appear to signal ex ante higher unobservable fund manager quality, at least not in the short run (here defined as three years of post-advertising excess returns data). If anything, fund advertising in linked to underperformance. Third, fund advertising affects people’s portfolio choices, even when advertising does not contain any information. Finally, fund advertising has significant economic effects: it steers people to portfolios with lower returns (through higher fees) and higher risk (a higher exposure to stocks, more active fund management, and much more local concentration). My results have many and important implications for a welfare analysis of fund advertising and portfolio choices, asset pricing models, and mutual fund industry policy making, and may serve as a starting point for wider and more formal analysis of the effects of advertising, marketing, and persuasion in financial markets. 1 Jain and Wu report that funds with an ad in Barron’s or Money magazine significantly underperform in a one-year post-ad period compared to benchmarks such as the S&P 500 index. Their dataset does not allow them to test whether the dollar amount of advertising expenditures signals higher quality. 3

The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 reviews economic theory and experimental evidence suggesting that fund advertising may affect people’s portfolio choices, and explains how such arguments may be tested empirically. Section 3 describes the event and the data. Section 4 reports the results and performs robustness checks. Section 5 estimates the economic effects of fund advertising on portfolio returns and risk. Section 6 concludes the paper, and suggests some extensions for future research. 2. 2.1. Advertising and portfolio choice: Theory Advertising as direct information An early literature on the economics of advertising started with a series of important papers by Nelson (1970, 1974). He emphasizes advertising’s information function.2 The most obvious procedure available to a rational consumer in obtaining information about the quality or price of a product or brand is costly search. For “search qualities” (i.e., qualities of a product that can be determined by inspection prior to the purchase of a brand, such as the style of a dress or a suit), advertising may provide direct information about product characteristics that are relevant to a consumer. By so doing, advertising reduces search costs, which will make consumers’ better off. When applying Nelson’s theory to fund advertising and portfolio choice, an obvious question to ask is: what attributes of mutual funds may advertising provide direct information about? Since there is little evidence that funds that have outperformed in the past will continue to do so,3 fund advertising about past returns does not appear directly informative. However, 2 See also Stigler (1961), who constructs a model of optimal search behavior, in which advertising reduces search costs, and thus price dispersion. 3 Hendricks, Patel and Zeckhauser (1993) and Brown and Goetzmann (1995) find evidence of persistence in fund performance over relatively short horizons (one to three years). Grinblatt and Titman (1992) suggest that a fund’s current performance can predict performance 5 to 10 years into the future. By contrast, Carhart (1997) suggests that most of the after-expenses performance persistence in his sample can be attributed to the one-year momentum effect of Jegadeesh and Titman (1993) in the underlying stock returns, with much of the remaining persistence attributable to the worst-performing funds. 4

because there is evidence that lower-fee funds outperform other funds net of fees (e.g., Elton, Gruber, Das and Hlavka (1993)), advertising may provide information about funds’ charges and expense ratios. Hortacsu and Syverson (2004) show that the dispersion in fees among U.S. index funds (a perfectly homogenous group of funds) is very large: the fee range stretches from below 10 to over 250 basis points per year. By providing information about fund fees, advertising has the potential of reducing search costs for investors in the mutual fund industry. I test the direct information hypothesis by systematically investigating the message of fund advertising using observational research methods than have previously been used by marketing researchers (and also in political science to identify the content/message of election campaign ads). 2.2. Advertising as a signal of quality Much advertising appears to convey no or little direct credible information about product characteristics. Motivated by this observation, Kihlstrom and Riordan (1984) and Milgrom and Roberts (1986) develop models in which advertising can still be informative, but indirectly so, if there exist market mechanisms that produce a positive relationship between product quality and advertising expenditures. In this case, consumers can correctly infer initially unobservable quality from observable advertising. That is, advertising may signal quality. Chevalier and Ellison (1999) study fund manager characteristics and performance for a large sample of mutual funds in the U.S. They document that some managers, in particular those who attended higher-SAT undergraduate institutions, have systematically higher risk-adjusted excess returns. Their finding that managers with certain observable characteristics outperform others raises the possibility that managers with certain (to investors and the econometrician) unobservable ability and talents are better than others. Under some conditions, such as learning 5

about quality through repeat business, fund managers of ex ante higher quality may use higher fund advertising expenditures to signal higher quality.4 I test the signaling hypothesis by examining whether funds with higher advertising expenditures are associated with higher post-advertising excess returns. 2.3. Advertising as mere exposure Behavioral models reject the idea that advertising only provides information. Instead, individuals’ choices are determined by both cognition and emotions (Kahneman, Slovic and Tversky (1982)). Two concepts from the theory of “mere exposure” (Zajonc (1968)) have been particularly actively explored in marketing practices and research: attitudes can also change without cognition; mere exposure makes attitudes more favorable.5 According to this theory, people are more likely to buy an advertised product as opposed to one that is not because the advertised product is more familiar to them. While Zajonc’s conclusion that “mere repeated exposure of the individual to a stimulus is a sufficient condition for the enhancement of his attitude toward it” (p.1) was a controversial idea in the 1960s, Bornstein (1989) has shown, through his meta-analysis of over 200 experiments, that mere exposure effects can be found in a lot of events and be replicated commonly. 4 Let me elaborate on the intuition behind the conditions that must be in place between funds and their investors for there to exist a separating equilibrium. Advertising can signal quality only if higher-quality funds find it profitable to invest in relatively more advertising than do lower-quality funds, and conversely. If advertising costs are the same for all funds, then the return to advertising must be greater for higherquality funds. The greater returns may e.g. be learning through repeat business. While it is optimal for higher-quality funds to initially spend a lot on advertising (because of the repeat business that it will generate when people realize that this is a higher-quality fund), it is not the case for lower-quality funds, because they will not be able to recoup their initial advertising expenditures as people will realize that they are of lower-quality and not give them any repeat business. 5 In Zajonc’s classical experiment, subjects were exposed to 12 stimuli of Turkish words, Chinese characters or yearbook photographs for two seconds with six frequencies (0, 1, 2, 5, 10, and 25). The instructions informed subjects that the study deals with “pronouncing foreign words,” ”learning a foreign language” and “visual memory,” and subjects were asked to rate how “good” they thought that the meaning of each word and character was, and how much they liked the person pictured in each photograph. While no information, only exposure, was communicated, subjects’ attitudes toward a particular word, character or photograph were shown to be significantly more positive as the frequency of their stimuli was increased. 6

In the area of mutual funds the evidence on mere exposure effects means that advertising of a fund may enhance people’s attitude towards the fund or the fund complex, although the fund advertising provides no information at all. That is, the choice of a particular fund or portfolio may not necessarily be the result of rational conscious information-processing by the investor. Instead, familiarity and awareness, created through fund advertising, may arise certain key positive emotions in investors, which make their attitudes towards a fund more favorable.6 My strategy for testing the mere exposure hypothesis is straightforward. I start by examining the extent to which fund ads provide direct information or signal higher postadvertising excess returns. In instances where they do not, but fund advertising is still found to affect people’s portfolio choices, mere exposure effects provide an alternative that cannot easily be ruled out. 3. 3.1. The event and data The event: Sweden’s social security reform In 2000, Sweden launched a partial privatization of its public pension system – the “Premium Pension”. In the reformed system, 2.5% of workers’ annual earnings are contributed to so-called individual savings accounts. In summary, the privatization plan had the following six important features:7 1. Participants were allowed to form their own portfolios by selecting from an approved list of Swedish and international mutual funds, some of which specialize in only one 6 Some recent financial research suggests that people like the familiar, also in financial markets contexts. Huberman (2001) shows a Regional Bell Operating Company’s shareholders tend to hold its shares rather than other RBOCs’ equity, and argues that this is evidence of people investing in the familiar. Benartzi (2001) reports that roughly a third of assets in large retirement savings plans are in company stock and that those who are “very familiar” with their employing firm show a somewhat higher correlation between past and predicted future own-company stock returns. 7 See Cronqvist and Thaler (2004) for a more extensive discussion of design choices in privatized social security systems in general, as well as the specific design choices that Sweden decided to go with. 7

type of asset, such as IT-funds, while others, life-cycle funds, are designed with retirement savings in mind. 2. One fund, Sjunde AP-Fonden’s Premiesparfonden, was chosen to be the default fund for anyone who does not make an active portfolio choice. 3. Any fund meeting standard fiduciary standards was allowed to enter the system. 4. Information about the funds, including fees, past performance, etc., was provided in the Fund Catalogue to all participants prior to the initial elections. 5. Balances and future contributions can be changed at any time, but unless some action is taken, the initial allocation determines all future contribution flows. 6. Funds, except the default fund, were allowed to advertise. With the above features, the Swedish “experiment” provides a unique opportunity to examine whether fund advertising affects people’s portfolio choices. First, real dollars were at stake for millions of retirement savers. Second, market entry determined the extensive menu of funds that participants could choose from. Finally, different funds chose very different levels of advertising expenditures, from no advertising at all to spending millions on advertising. 3.2. Data sources and summary statistics This paper combines two very detailed datasets from the event, one on people’s portfolio choices, and one on fund advertising. The dataset on people’s portfolio choices comes from the Premium Pension Authority (Premiepensionsmyndigheten, or PPM), the government authority that administrates the individual savings accounts in the reformed pension system. Panel A of Table 1 shows that as many as 4.4 million workers allocated a total of 5.6 billion dollars. Initially, the size of the accounts ranged from 10 to 2,639. The mean was 1,265 dollars. The average amount may seem small. However, as most people exhibit a status quo or default bias in their retirement savings accounts (e.g., Samuelson and Zeckhauser (1988) and Madrian and Shea (2001)), the present value of a worker’s future contribution flows is many times greater than these 8

“year 0” numbers alone suggest (in particular for younger people for whom the new system is more critical). The dataset on fund advertising comes from a Swedish marketing research company, MarketWatch. I have manually collected and compiled a large dataset of fund advertisements and commercials by searching for all the funds and fund complexes that were part of the reformed pension system in the company’s proprietary database. This database contains practically all advertisements and commercials that appear in Swedish print and broadcast media: Advertisements that appear in more than 250 newspapers, and in the popular press and professional journals, as well as outdoor ads on billboards and busses, and even in subway stations, etc. Commercials from all the major television and radio networks, and also those appearing in the largest movie theaters. Panel B shows that during the two years prior to the initial portfolio choices, funds spent a total of 94.4 million on advertising. The dataset contains 23,604 advertisements (47.2% of the total expenditures), ranging in size and scope from small local newspaper ads to large billboard-type ads, such as one covering the exterior of a 34 story office building in downtown Stockholm. There are also 20,647 commercials (52.8% of the total expenditures), ranging from two-second weather sponsorship spots to an eight and a half minute long “infomercial” on how to choose (the fund complex’s) mutual funds. Advertisements in print media and television commercials account for about 90 percent of all the ad expenditures. Finally, Panel C shows summary statistics for the funds in the list that people could choose from. 4. 4.1. Results Descriptive evidence Before presenting the main results and testing the hypotheses, it is useful to consider some simple descriptive evidence. First, I present evidence on “advertising recall” from a large 9

survey, an exit poll of 1,083 retirement savers (selected to be representative of the population), implemented by a leading phone survey company (Sifo) during the days following people’s initial portfolio choices. Figure 1 reports fund advertising recall ratios for four categories of fund advertising. We see e.g. that as many as 75% of the investors recalled seeing some advertisement in a newspaper or other print media, and 86% recalled seeing some TV-commercial. Thus, most investors were exposed to at least some fund advertising before choosing their initial portfolios. Second, I report evidence on the effects of the aggregate level of fund advertising. Figure 2 shows total fund advertising and the proportion of active portfolio choices each year during the period 2000-2005. As can be seen, aggregate advertising was much greater in year 2000, simply because as many as 4.4 million workers made their first elections (and 5.6 billion were at stake for fund managers), than in e.g. year 2005, when only 116,000 new workers joined the plan (and only 17.4 million were at stake). The observation that the fraction of active choices is much higher in years with more advertising suggests a link between fund advertising and people’s portfolio choices. Finally, I report evidence on whether funds that spent more on fund advertising were able to attract more of investors’ money. Figure 3 plots the dollar allocation to a fund as a function of the fund’s level of expenditures on fund advertising prior to people’s initial portfolio choices. The correlation is 0.544 and statistically significant (p-value 0.000). Of course, this evidence does not say anything about why fund advertising affects people’s portfolio choices, i.e. whether it provides direct information, signals higher quality, or affects people through mere exposure. Furthermore, this positive correlation is merely suggestive of an association between advertising and portfolio choices because advertising may be proxying for some other characteristics affecting people’s portfolio choices. 10

4.2. Evidence on advertising as direct information I test the direct information hypothesis by systematically investigating the information content of the fund advertising. To do so, I implement Resnik and Stern (1977) content analysis method for identifying messages in ads. They classify “cues” in ads into the following 14 categories: price, performance, independent research, company research, availability, components or contents, new ideas, quality, special offers or promotions, guarantee, nutrition, packaging or shape, safety, and taste. Several of them, like nutrition or taste, are obviously not applicable to the mutual fund industry. To keep the analysis simple and tractable, I choose to classify cues in fund advertising into three broad categories: 1. Fee cue. A fund ad is considered to have a “price,” i.e. fee, cue if it contains a reference to the fund’s charges. 2. Performance cue. I aggregate Resnik and Stern’s three cue categories performance, independent research and company research into one category as they, in the fund industry, are all related to past performance (returns). A fund ad has a performance cue if it contains the fund’s return for some period (e.g., past year, 5 years or the fund’s lifetime), Morningstar’s star rating, other independent research company’s rankings, or any other return comparison, with e.g. an index or category, chosen by the advertising fund itself. 3. Other cue. These are ads that do not have a fee or performance cue. Operationally, I have implemented the content analysis along these lines by combining information available in the content description field in MarketWatch’s database as well as information from the National Library of Sweden, which by law is required to store, indefinitely, one copy of all Swedish published material for research purposes. Table 2 contains examples of fee, performance, and other cues, and the Appendix provides one illustration for each advertising/cue category. The results of the content analysis 11

deserve some comments, because this is the first attempt to systematically identify the message of fund advertising that retirement savers and other individual investors are exposed to. First, as can be seen in the table, fee advertising contains a message such as e.g. “If the price of milk goes up. Does it then taste better?” Only 9.8% of the fee advertising (0.8% of all advertising) contains information that allows investors to actually compare the expense ratio of the advertised fund to that of other funds in the fund’s category. An example of this observation is an ad stating “Compare our fees!” Still, this ad contained no information about the expense ratio of the advertised fund, nor of any of the fund’s competitors’ charges. Second, performance ads emphasize Morningstar’s stars or past returns, some over the past year, others over 5 years, yet others over the lifetime of the fund, supposedly depending on what frame shows the greatest performance advantage for the advertised fund. More importantly, performance ads tend to involve “hot segments” of the overall market portfolio, with high past raw returns. Since the Swedish social security reform took place in year 2000, it should not come as a surprise that as much as 96.9% of the performance advertising in my sample involved stock or mixed funds, in particular those tilted towards information technology stocks, a very hot market segment in year 2000. Finally, the category other advertising involves a wide variety of different content. For example, one fund complex featured actor Harrison Ford in print ads, and also placed TVcommercials in the blocks of the Swedish television premiere of the movie Air Force One, starring Mr. Ford. As can be seen in the table, this is one of many examples of ads playing on different facets of the phenomenon of familiarity. Of course, associating a fund with something that investors are already familiar with may be very useful under the mere exposure explanation for fund advertising. The observation that funds tend to differentiate themselves by their advertising -- one fund uses Harrison Ford others something else -- is interesting, but it is beyond the scope of this paper to evaluate the relative effectiveness of different fund advertising strategies. 12

Table 4 shows the proportions of advertising dollars that were spent on fee, performance, and other advertising, respectively. As we can see, only 7.9 percent of the advertising involves ads with a fee cue. By contrast, performance advertising accounts for as much as 30.0 percent, while the rest is advertising containing another cue. Consistent with much research on other, non-financial, advertising, we see that fund advertising in print media is relatively more informative about fund fees than commercials: 13.5% vs. 2.9% of the advertising dollars went to fee advertising. Taken together, the conte

economic effects of fund advertising on portfolio returns and risk. Section 6 concludes the paper, and suggests some extensions for future research. 2. Advertising and portfolio choice: Theory 2.1. Advertising as direct information An early literature on the economics of advertising started with a series of important papers by Nelson (1970, 1974).

Related Documents:

the advertising is placed, the language of the advertising, and the release date identified in the advertising. Advertising that is intended for international audiences may nonetheless be subject to these Rules if, in the opinion of the senior executive of the Advertising Administration, the advertising is being made available to a significant

of digital advertising should grow by an additional 13.5% during 2022. On this basis, digital advertising should account for 64.4% of total advertising in 2021, up from 60.5% in 2020 and 52.1% in 2019 . Excluding China, where digital advertising shares are particularly high, global digital advertising accounts for 58.7% of all advertising in 2021.

YouTube video ads that are played for at least :30, or in full if the ad is less than :30 Ipsos/Google Advertising Attention Research 2016 9 Visual Attention is defined as: time looking at advertising as a percent of advertising time TV Advertising Time All YouTube Mobile Advertising Time Paid YouTube Mobile* Advertising Time (Non-skipped)

The Academy of Dental Learning & OSHA Training CESupport@DentalLearning.org 1101 Sibley Memorial Hwy Ste. 211 St. Paul, MN 55118 (800) 522-1207 Academy - Dental Learning & OSHA Training is an ADA CERP Recognized provider. ADA CERP is a service of the American Dental Association to assist dental professionals in

The Academy of Dental Learning & OSHA Training 1101 Sibley Memorial Hwy Ste. 211 St. Paul, MN 55118 (800) 522-1207 CESupport@DentalLearning.org Academy - Dental Learning & OSHA Training is an ADA CERP Recognized provider. ADA CERP is a service of the American Dental Association to assist dental professionals in .

ADVERTISING PORTFOLIO 2021 FUTURE ADVERTISING PARTNER, We would like to thank you for considering The Blade for your Advertising needs. We will connect you with the best of . For more information, contact a Blade Advertising Consultant at 419-724-6350 or visit blademediakit.com. September 2021 September 2021. Strip Ad Blade Notes

the TfL advertising estate, one of the most valuable out-of-home advertising networks in the world. It has a particular focus on the . implementation of the TfL Advertising Policy, which sets out criteria for the acceptance of advertising on the estate and covers the types of advertising we run and the complaints received and resolved.

3 Lorsqu’un additif présent dans un arôme, un additif ou une enzyme alimentaire a une fonction technologique dans la denrée alimentaire à laquelle il est adjoint, il est considéré comme additif de cette denrée alimentaire, et non de l’arôme, de l’additif ou de l’enzyme alimentaire ajouté et doit dès lors remplir les conditions d’emploi définies pour la denrée en question .