Central Banks Communications And Monetary Policy

3y ago
41 Views
4 Downloads
316.62 KB
22 Pages
Last View : 3d ago
Last Download : 3m ago
Upload by : Grant Gall
Transcription

IN-DEPTH ANALYSISRequested by the ECON committeeCentral BanksCommunications andMonetary PolicyMonetary Dialogue September 2018Policy Department for Economic, Scientific and Quality of Life PoliciesAuthor: Professor Karl WhelanDirectorate-General for Internal PoliciesPE 626.067 - September 2018EN

Central BanksCommunications andMonetary PolicyMonetary Dialogue September 2018AbstractCommunications about plans for future monetary policy are oneof the key tools through which central banks can affect theeconomy. The addition of non-standard policies such asquantitative easing has complicated communication for centralbanks and there have been some lessons for the ECB to learnfrom communications mistakes made by other central banks inrecent years. The ECB has so far done well in handling thecommunications issues relating to the ending of its AssetPurchase Programme but it faces a number of communicationschallenges as it seeks to normalise monetary policy.This document was provided by Policy Department A at therequest of the Economic and Monetary Affairs Committee.

This document was requested by the European Parliament's Committee on Economic and MonetaryAffairs.AUTHORSKarl WHELAN, University College DublinADMINISTRATOR RESPONSIBLEDario PATERNOSTEREDITORIAL ASSISTANTJanetta CUJKOVALINGUISTIC VERSIONSOriginal: ENABOUT THE EDITORPolicy departments provide in-house and external expertise to support EP committees and otherparliamentary bodies in shaping legislation and exercising democratic scrutiny over EU internalpolicies.To contact the Policy Department or to subscribe for updates, please write to:Policy Department for Economic, Scientific and Quality of Life PoliciesEuropean ParliamentB-1047 BrusselsEmail: Poldep-Economy-Science@ep.europa.euManuscript completed in September 2018 European Union, 2018This document is available on the internet n/monetary-dialogue.htmlDISCLAIMER AND COPYRIGHTThe opinions expressed in this document are the sole responsibility of the authors and do notnecessarily represent the official position of the European Parliament.Reproduction and translation for non-commercial purposes are authorised, provided the source isacknowledged and the European Parliament is given prior notice and sent a copy.

Central Banks Communications and Monetary PolicyCONTENTSLIST OF FIGURES3EXECUTIVE SUMMARY4INTRODUCTION5CENTRAL BANK TRANSPARENCY OVER THE PAST 30 YEARS62.1. Theoretical Arguments Against and For Transparency62.1.1. Anchoring of Inflation Expectations62.1.2. Discretion versus Commitment72.1.3. Financial Market Efficiency and the Term Structure of Interest Rates82.2. The Evolution of Central Bank Communications2.2.1. The Federal Reserve892.2.2. The ECB10COMMUNICATIONS PROBLEMS IN RECENT YEARS123.1. Forward Guidance Failures123.1.1. The Fed’s Unemployment Rate Guidance123.1.2. The Bank of England’s Unemployment Rate Guidance133.1.3. Some Lessons133.2. QE-Specific Problems: The “Taper Tantrum”13COMMUNICATIONS ISSUES CURRENTLY FACING THE ECB164.1. The ECB’s Exit from QE164.2. Other Communications Issues for ECB174.2.1. How High Could Rates Go?174.2.2. Managing the Balance Sheet174.2.3. Credibility of the Inflation Target174.2.4. Leadership and Continuity18REFERENCES19LIST OF FIGURESFigure 1:Number of Words in Post-FOMC Statements10Figure 2:Ten Year US Treasury Bond Yield and Effective Federal Funds Rate (Daily Data)15PE 626.0673

IPOL Policy Department for Economic, Scientific and Quality of Life PoliciesEXECUTIVE SUMMARY Communications about plans for future monetary policy are one of the key tools through whichcentral banks can affect the economy. In particular, the yields on long-term financial instruments depend on expectations of futuremonetary policy and are sensitive to guidance from central banks. For many years, central banks were highly secretive about their decision-making procedures,fearing that revealing too much information would restrict their flexibility. Central banks around the world have gradually accepted that transparency in communicating theirgoals and strategies to the public helps to make policy more effective. Experience over the past two decades with periods in which policy rates are at or close to zero hashighlighted the importance of providing forward guidance on the likely length of time that interestrates will remain very low. The Federal Reserve and Bank of England’s experiences with using specified numerical values ofthe unemployment rate as a trigger to raise interest rates were not successful. These central bankskept policy rates at zero after the “trigger” level of unemployment was reached because of theabsence of inflationary pressures. The ECB should not use this tactic of specifying a specific level ofunemployment (or any other indicator) as dictating the end of its zero interest rate policy. The addition of non-standard policies such as quantitative easing (QE) has complicatedcommunication for central banks. The public will expect interest rate increases to come after a QEprogramme has ceased so the central bank can provide additional information on the future pathof interest rates by signalling whether it is planning to continue its assets purchases at its currentrate or planning to reduce them and also by signalling a timeline for the end of the programmes. The 2013 “taper tantrum” event shows how central banks can mishandle their communicationsstrategy in ending a QE programme and trigger unwanted financial tightening. The ECB has so far done well in handling the communications issues relating to the ending of itsAsset Purchase Programme but it faces a number of communications challenges as it seeks tonormalise monetary policy, most notably in relation to how high policy rates will go in the nextcycle. Over the longer term, the ECB faces a communication problem in establishing its commitment toa symmetric 2 percent inflation target because it has undershot this target for so long. Perhaps the key communications issue facing the ECB is the need to replace Mario Draghi withsomeone who agrees with his approach to monetary policy and who will provide continuity ratherthan a sharp change in policies.4PE 626.067

Central Banks Communications and Monetary PolicyINTRODUCTIONCommunication with the public is an area where central banking has changed remarkably over thepast three decades. As Blinder at al (2008) put it in a survey paper on central bank communications “Afew decades ago, conventional wisdom in central banking circles held that monetary policymakers shouldsay as little as possible, and say it cryptically.” Today, however, central banks communicate with thepublic via a wide range of methods such as formal statements after policy meetings, press conferencesand regular speeches by members of policy-making boards. Over the past decade, the language incentral bank statements about what the bank intends to do in the future is more important than anyconcrete decision made (or not made) during monetary policy meetings.Despite this general consensus that central banks should be more open with the public than in thepast, there are still a wide range of different approaches taken by central banks to communicating theirpolicy stances and future intentions. There have also been a number of cases in recent years whereleading central banks have communicated key policy changes poorly or lost credibility by failing tostick to policies that they had signalled. So central banks face a delicate balance act in getting theircommunications right.Non-standard monetary policies such as quantitative easing (QE) have brought a new set of challengesto central bank communications. On the one hand, the ability to signal the length of time thatpurchases programmes are in place, and also the quantity of purchases that are planned, can be auseful way to communicate monetary policy plans during an extended period of policy rates being setat zero, as is the current situation in the euro area. On the other hand, the Federal Reserve’s handlingof its phasing out of its QE programme, which lead to the so-called “taper tantrum” in financial markets,provides an example of where the complexity of these non-standard instruments can make it hard forcentral banks to get across the message they really intend.The ECB’s June Governing Council meeting has signalled a phasing out and then ending of its balancesheet expansion and also provided new guidance about the future path of policy rates. As I discusslater in this paper, the ECB has handled these communications well so far. This reflects a soundcommunications strategy from the ECB but the calm response from financial markets may also matterbecause market participants have learned a lot over the past few years about how QE programmesimpact the economy and have seen successful ends to such programmes in both the UK and the US.This has probably eased the ECB’s difficulties in communicating to financial markets how its QEprogramme will end.The structure of the rest of this paper is as follows. Section 2 provides a review of the arguments forand against transparency in central bank communications and reviews how communications havechanged over time at the Fed and the ECB. Section 3 discusses some of the difficulties that haveoccurred with central bank communications in recent years, focusing on the Fed and Bank of England’splans (subsequently cancelled) to raise policy rates once unemployment rates fell below a predetermined benchmark and also on the 2013 “taper tantrum” provoked by Federal Reserveannouncements related to the phasing out of QE. Section 4 concludes by discussing thecommunication challenges facing the ECB at present and in the coming years.PE 626.0675

IPOL Policy Department for Economic, Scientific and Quality of Life PoliciesCENTRAL BANK TRANSPARENCY OVER THE PAST 30 YEARSIn this section, I first discuss the arguments that have been used both against and for transparency incentral bank communications, describing how the balance of opinion in both the academic and centralbanking communities have moved towards favouring more transparency. I will then briefly discusshow communications strategies have evolved over time at the Federal Reserve and the ECB.2.1.Theoretical Arguments Against and For TransparencyGiven the large amount of communication from modern central banks, it may be hard to understandwhy central banks were so secretive in the past. One useful set of evidence that explains why theFederal Reserve was so secretive was documented by Marvin Goodfriend (1986). Goodfriend’s paperdescribes a legal case brought against the Fed under the Freedom of Information Act, requesting themto disclose their policy directive after each meeting of the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC).This directive was a set of instructions to the managers of the “System Open Market Account” (i.e. theoperations desk at the New York Fed) including a set of “tolerance ranges” for the money supply andthe federal funds rate. The Fed opposed this request and after legal proceedings that lasted from 1976to 1981, they eventually won the case.In legal proceedings, the Federal Reserve made a number of arguments against releasing thisdocument immediately after their meetings. They argued that issuing an immediate statement wouldprovide an unfair advantage to a small group of investment banks that would get access to thestatement before the general public. They also believed that issuing statements could constrain theirpolicy actions in the future, perhaps because once their policy objectives have been made clear, theyworried the public would lose faith in them if they then began pursuing different objectives over thefollowing months. Finally, they worried that these announcements would cause volatility in financialmarkets due to financial markets regularly reassessing the policy stance based on statements.In 1984, Fed Chairman Paul Volcker (quoted in Blinder et al, 2008) supported the policy of not issuingstatements on the following grounds:“One danger in immediate release of the directive is that certain assumptions might be made that weare committed to certain operations that are, in fact, dependent on future events, and theseinterpretations and expectations would tend to diminish our needed operational flexibility.”In contrast to this official position, the academic economist community had by 1984, been movingtowards a position that central banks should be transparent and communicate their policies and goalsto the public in a clear fashion. Here, I describe three different strands of academic literature thatpointed in this direction.2.1.1.Anchoring of Inflation ExpectationsDuring the 1960s, macroeconomists generally believed there was a “Phillips curve “ trade-off betweeninflation and unemployment. Policy-makers could run a hot economy with a low unemployment rateat the expense of putting up with somewhat higher inflation. Milton Friedman’s famous 1967 addressto the American Economics Association shed doubts on this idea and the subsequent macroeconomicevents also showed this was a flawed approach. Friedman pointed out that if inflation has been higherdue to a low unemployment rate, then workers will become used to this higher inflation rate and cometo expect it. With these higher inflation expectations, the real wage increases required in a tight labourmarket will require even higher inflation, which could fuel further rises in inflation expectations and setoff an inflationary spiral.6PE 626.067

Central Banks Communications and Monetary PolicyAs macroeconomic textbooks were revised from the 1970s onwards to focus on “expectationsaugmented” versions of the Phillips curve, academic focus on central banking turned to how centralbanks could manage the public’s inflation expectations. Clear and consistent communications wereone important tool in keeping the public’s inflation expectations well anchored.With this thinking becoming more prevalent, central banks have become increasingly focused in thepast two decades on communicating their intentions in relation to inflation. There have been manyelements to this movement. Central bank legal mandates have in many cases been refined to makeclear that controlling inflation is a key or perhaps primary goal. Many central banks now alsocommunicate an explicit target rate of inflation to the public with the academic case for inflationtargeting well summarised in a 1999 book co-authored by Ben Bernanke, who later became FedChairman and established a clear inflation target.2.1.2.Discretion versus CommitmentThe central bank officials of the 1970s objected to the release of statements about policy actions onthe grounds that it reduced their flexibility to make the best decisions at each point in time because itmay commit them to be more consistent in their actions. However, the academic literature onexpectations and macroeconomic policy of the late 1970s had largely concluded that completeflexibility and discretion in monetary policy-making was not always such a good thing.In a famous paper, subsequently mentioned in the Nobel prize citation, Finn Kydland and EdwardPrescott (1977) showed that in “dynamic” environments in which policy actions can affect thebehaviour of the private sector and vice versa, purely flexible policy-making featuring completediscretion to take separate period-by-period decisions, was not usually the best approach. Instead, theydemonstrated that a policy that committed to a particular set course of action could generally producea better outcome.The Phillips curve relationship between inflation and unemployment was one of the examples featuredin Kydland and Prescott’s paper. The fact that there may be a short-run trade-off between inflation andunemployment (before inflation expectations catch up with reality) will generally lead policy-makerswith discretion to attempt to exploit this trade off. However, as developed in many subsequent paperssuch as Barro and Gordon (1983) , better outcomes can be obtained through a commitment to notexploit this trade-off and instead focus on delivering low inflation. In the “discretion” equilibrium inthese models, the public knows that central bank will attempt to exploit the Phillips trade-off and thismeans higher expected and actual inflation but the average unemployment rate still ends up beingthe so-called “natural rate”. The “commitment” equilibrium has the same average unemployment ratebut a lower inflation rate. 1These insights have had a practical effect on central banks. Explicit inflation targets and morearticulated policy mandates can be seen as ways to commit central banks to take the correct long-termcourse of action rather than setting policy in a highly flexible way. The global move towards increasedindependence for central banks can also be seen as an implication of these ideas, since politicians tendto have a relatively short election-focused time horizon for decisions and are thus less likely to adopt along-run commitment-based approach to monetary policy.1A simplified version of this kind of model is presented in my undergraduate lecture notes available athttp://www.karlwhelan.com/IMB/part15.pdf.PE 626.0677

IPOL Policy Department for Economic, Scientific and Quality of Life Policies2.1.3.Financial Market Efficiency and the Term Structure of Interest RatesAnother academic development that influenced central bank practice on communications was thedevelopment of the efficient markets hypothesis for financial markets. As the macroeconomistsfocused on the effect of rationality in expectations formation on inflation, finance economists such asEugene Fama presented evidence that financial markets seemed to process information in a relativelyefficient manner.For monetary policy, the efficient markets hypothesis has particularly important implications for thedetermination of longer-term interest rates. Some of the interest rates that households, governmentsand businesses borrow at are closely related to the short-term policy rate set by central banks:Adjustable rate mortgages for households or short-term “treasury bills” for government, for example.However, many other borrowing contracts have longer-term fixed rates. Ehrmann and Ziegelmeyer(2014) calculate that 45 percent of euro area mortgages are adjustable rate, with the majority beingfixed rate with fix terms of various lengths. Most government debt is also long-term with fixed interestrates.If markets process information efficiently, then arbitrage relationships require that longer-term interestrates be determined by the expected value of future short-term interest rates. Similarly, other “longlived” assets such as stocks and exchange rates will be affected by the expected value of short-terminterest rates in the coming years.From this point of view, not only should central banks communicate with the public about their futureplans for monetary policy but these communications are a crucial vehicle through which monetarypolicy affects the economy. This modern viewpoint on the monetary policy transmission mechanismwas laid out by well-known macroeconomist Michael Woodford (2001) at the 2001 Jackson Holeconference for central bankers. He informed his audience:“the current level of overnight interest rates as such is of negligible importance for economic decisionmaking; if a change in the overnight rate were thought to imply only a change in the cost of overnightborrowing for that one night, then even a large change (say, a full percentage point increase) wouldmake little difference to anyone’s spending decisions. The effectiveness of changes in central-banktargets for overnight rates in affecting spending decisions (and, hence, ultimately pricing andemployment decisions) is wholly dependent upon the impact of such actions upon other financialmarket prices, such as longer-term interest rates, equity prices, and exchange rates . it is the

As Blinder at al (2008) put it in a survey paper on central bank communications “ A few decades ago, conventional wisdom in central banking circles held that monetary policymakers should say as little as possible, and say it cryptically.” Today, however, central banks communicate with the public via a wide range of methods such as formal statements after policy meetings, press conferences .

Related Documents:

The term 'monetary integration' presents some definitional difficulties in international monetary theory. It has been described as a generic term connoting various categories of cooperation on monetary matters between or among countries.2 The International Monetary Fund (IMF) describes these categories of monetary integration as Exchange

central banks in order to gather more detailed information on central banks’ views on climate-related measures and the current state of play regarding their potential application. The survey was conducted in early summer 2020 and received responses from 26 central banks across the world, including two monetary unions, hence representing

The Monetary Approach The monetary approach is one of the central pillars of international macroeconomics. Its point of departure is the so called monetary model, which identifies the factors affecting long-term nominal exchange rates. The monetary model was originally used as a framework of analy

The Monetary Approach to International Macroeconomics The monetary approach is one of the central pillars of international macroeconomics. Its point of departure is the so called monetary model, which identifies the factors affecting long-term nominal exchange rates. The monetary model was originally used a

1. New normal in monetary policy 2. Lessons from monetary policy exit mistakes of Sweden, the US and the UK 3. ECB monetary policy exit when the inflation out

A key goal of monetary theory is to provide us with an account of the mechanisms through which those effects arise, i.e., the transmission mechanism of monetary policy. Central banks do not change interest rates in an arbitrary or whimsical manner. Understanding what should be the objectives of monetary policy and how the latter should

Monetary policy Framework of Ethiopia Economic Research and Monetary Policy Process, NBE 2 II. Monetary Policy Objective The principal objective of the monetary policy of the National Bank of Ethiopia is to maintain price & exchange rate stability and support sustainab

Abrasive water jet can do this with quality results but, generally is too expensive compared to plasma, laser or punching. 5. Cut Geometry Abrasive waterjet cuts have straight edges with a slight amount of taper. Kerf width is controlled by the orifice/nozzle combination. Cuts in thicker materials generally require larger combinations with more abrasive usage. The kerf width can be as small as .