The Macroeconomic Effects Of Student Debt Cancellation

1y ago
15 Views
2 Downloads
1.59 MB
68 Pages
Last View : 7d ago
Last Download : 3m ago
Upload by : Milena Petrie
Transcription

THEMACROECONOMICEFFECTS OFSTUDENT DEBTCANCELLATIONScott Fullwiler, Stephanie Kelton, Catherine Ruetschlin, and Marshall SteinbaumFebruary 2018Levy EconomicsInstituteof Bard College

2Student Debt Cancellation Report 2018

THE MACROECONOMIC EFFECTS OFSTUDENT DEBT CANCELLATIONScott Fullwiler, Stephanie Kelton, Catherine Ruetschlin, and Marshall SteinbaumLevy Economics Institute of Bard College3

Table of ContentsEXECUTIVE SUMMARY6INTRODUCTION7SECTION 1: THE ECONOMIC OPPORTUNITY OF STUDENT DEBT CANCELLATION9Social Investment in Higher EducationThe current state of student debtThe social costs of student debt91012The Distributional Consequences of Student Debt, Student Debt Cancellation, and Debt-Free CollegeThe distribution of student debt and debt burden in the cross sectionThe evolution of the distribution of student debt burdens over timeWhat does the evolution of student debt tell us about the labor market?How does student debt interact with longstanding economic disparaties?1314151616The real distributional impact of student debt cancellation and free or debt-free college17SECTION 2: THE MECHANICS OF STUDENT DEBT CANCELLATION18The Mechanics of Student Debt Cancellation Carried Out by the GovernmentCurrent servicing of student loans from a balance sheet perspectivePossible methods of government-financed student debt cancellationThe government cancels the Department of Education’s loans all at onceThe government cancels the Department of Education’s loans as borrowers’ payments come dueGovernment-led debt cancellation where the government assumes payments on student loans issued byprivate investorsGovernment-led debt cancellation where the government simultaneously purchases and then cancels loans ownedby private investorsGovernment-led debt cancellation where the government purchases student loans issued by private investors andcancels principal as payments come dueConcluding remarks on government-led cancellation of privately owned student loansConcluding remarks on government-led debt cancellation181819202122The Mechanics of Student Debt Cancellation Carried Out by the Federal ReserveThe Federal Reserve purchases the Department of Education’s loansSome fundamentals of the Federal Reserve’s remittances and their relevance to student loan cancellationThe Federal Reserve cancels the Department of Education’s loans all at onceThe Federal Reserve cancels debt service payments for the Department of Education’s loansThe Federal Reserve assumes debt service payments for loans owned by private investorsThe Federal Reserve purchases and cancels loans owned by private investorsThe Federal Reserve purchases loans owned by private investors and cancels debt service paymentsPotential options to avoid costs to the federal government of student loan cancellation carried out by theFederal Reserve2727282829313233344Student Debt Cancellation Report 201824252626

SECTION 3: SIMULATING STUDENT DEBT CANCELLATION36Models and Assumptions Used for Simulating Student Debt CancellationIntroduction to the Moody’s modelIntroduction to the Fair modelAssumptions for the simulated student debt cancellationBaseline values and macroeconometric simulation3636373738Simulation ResultsConclusions from simulations3945Omitted Benefits and Costs of Student Debt CancellationSmall business formationCollege degree attainmentHousehold formationCredit scoresHousehold vulnerability in business cycle downturnsMoral hazard46464748484849CONCLUSION50APPENDIX A: SIMULATION DATA SERIES52APPENDIX B: DEPARTMENT OF EDUCATION LOANS AND THE BUDGET DEFICIT55APPENDIX C: DIGRESSION ON THE FED’S OPERATIONS58NOTES61REFERENCES64Levy Economics Institute of Bard College5

Executive Summary1More than 44 million Americans are caught in a student debttrap. Collectively, they owe nearly 1.4 trillion on outstandingstudent loan debt. Research shows that this level of debt hurtsthe US economy in a variety of ways, holding back everythingfrom small business formation to new home buying, and evenmarriage and reproduction. It is a problem that policymakershave attempted to mitigate with programs that offer refinancing or partial debt cancellation. But what if something far moreambitious were tried? What if the population were freed frommaking any future payments on the current stock of outstanding student loan debt? Could it be done, and if so, how? Whatwould it mean for the US economy?This report seeks to answer those very questions. Theanalysis proceeds in three sections: the first explores the currentUS context of increasing college costs and reliance on debt tofinance higher education; the second section works through thebalance sheet mechanics required to liberate Americans fromstudent loan debt; and the final section simulates the economiceffects of this debt cancellation using two models, Ray Fair’s USMacroeconomic Model (“the Fair model”) and Moody’s USMacroeconomic Model.Several important implications emerge from this analysis.Student debt cancellation results in positive macroeconomicfeedback effects as average households’ net worth and disposable income increase, driving new consumption and investmentspending. In short, we find that debt cancellation lifts GDP,decreases the average unemployment rate, and results in littleinflationary pressure (all over the 10-year horizon of our simulations), while interest rates increase only modestly. Thoughthe federal budget deficit does increase, state-level budget positions improve as a result of the stronger economy. The use oftwo models with contrasting long-run theoretical foundationsoffers a plausible range for each of these effects and demonstrates the robustness of our results.A one-time policy of student debt cancellation, in whichthe federal government cancels the loans it holds directly andtakes over the financing of privately owned loans on behalf ofborrowers, results in the following macroeconomic effects (alldollar values are in real, inflation-adjusted terms, using 2016 asthe base year):26Student Debt Cancellation Report 2018 The policy of debt cancellation could boost real GDP byan average of 86 billion to 108 billion per year. Over the10-year forecast, the policy generates between 861 billionand 1,083 billion in real GDP (2016 dollars). Eliminating student debt reduces the average unemployment rate by 0.22 to 0.36 percentage points over the 10-yearforecast. Peak job creation in the first few years following the elimination of student loan debt adds roughly 1.2 million to 1.5 million new jobs per year. The inflationary effects of cancelling the debt are macroeconomically insignificant. In the Fair model simulations,additional inflation peaks at about 0.3 percentage points andturns negative in later years. In the Moody’s model, the effectis even smaller, with the pickup in inflation peaking at a triv ial 0.09 percentage points.Nominal interest rates rise modestly. In the early years, theFederal Reserve raises target rates 0.3 to 0.5 percentage points;in later years, the increase falls to just 0.2 percentage points.The effect on nominal longer-term interest rates peaks at 0.25to 0.5 percentage points and declines thereafter, settling at0.21 to 0.35 percentage points.The net budgetary effect for the federal government is modest,with a likely increase in the deficit-to-GDP ratio of 0.65 to 0.75percentage points per year. Depending on the federal government’s budget position overall, the deficit ratio could rise moremodestly, ranging between 0.59 and 0.61 percentage points.However, given that the costs of funding the Department ofEducation’s student loans have already been incurred (discussed in detail in Section 2), the more relevant estimatesfor the impacts on the government’s budget position relativeto current levels are an annual increase in the deficit ratio ofbetween 0.29 and 0.37 percentage points. (This is explained infurther detail in Appendix B.)State budget deficits as a percentage of GDP improve by about0.11 percentage points during the entire simulation period.Research suggests many other positive spillover effects that arenot accounted for in these simulations, including increases insmall business formation, degree attainment, and householdformation, as well as improved access to credit and reducedhousehold vulnerability to business cycle downturns. Thus,our results provide a conservative estimate of the macroeffects of student debt liberation.

IntroductionThere is mounting evidence that the escalation of student debtin the United States is an impediment to both household financial stability and aggregate consumption and investment. Theincreasing demand for college credentials coupled with risingcosts of attendance have led more students than ever before totake on student loans, with higher average balances. This debtburden reduces household disposable income and consumption and investment opportunities, with spillover effects acrossthe economy. At the same time, the social benefits of investmentin higher education—including human capital accumulation,social mobility, and the greater tax revenues and social contri-market entry positions provided incentives for more studentsto take on debt. This student loan debt imposes a significantlyhigher burden on household finances than ever before, as stagnant real incomes and higher average balances combine todivert a larger portion of household resources toward debt service and away from consumption and investment.It is possible for the federal government to reduce or removethe burden of student loan debt as a means of direct supportto household spending. In this report, we examine the mechanisms that facilitate debt cancellation using T-accounts to mapthe transactions associated with the program. In a governmentfinanced cancellation program, the current loan portfolio of theDepartment of Education is cancelled and the federal government either purchases and cancels or takes over the paymentsfor privately owned loans. One of the more significant take-butions that flow from a highly productive population—remaincentral to the economic advantages enjoyed by the United States.In this context, students, educators, and policymakers havecalled for a range of solutions to the rising cost of college andthe encumbrance of borrowers. In this report, we examine themacroeconomic effects of one of the boldest of these proposals: a program of outright student debt cancellation financedby the federal government. If student debt is indeed dampening household economic activity, we expect liberation fromthis debt to produce a stimulus effect that will partially offsetthe cost of the program. In fact, we find that cancelling studentdebt would have a meaningful stimulus effect, particularly inthe first five years, characterized by greater economic activity asmeasured by GDP and employment, with only moderate effectson the federal budget deficit, interest rates, and inflation over theforecast horizon. Overall, the macroeconomic consequences ofstudent debt cancellation demonstrate that a reorientation of UShigher education policy can include ambitious policy proposalslike a total cancellation of all outstanding student loan debt.Higher education is a valuable social investment, withresearch demonstrating social returns up to five times the dollaramount of public spending in the United States (OECD 2015).The diffusion of these benefits across the economy makes thema classic example of positive externalities, a condition in whichindividual cost/benefit calculations that omit social benefits willresult in a market failure. In these cases, public investment isnecessary to avoid chronic underinvestment. Yet in the UnitedStates over the past three decades, public funding of higher education has been in decline (SHEEO 2015). At the same time,the increasing need for a college credential to access key laboraways here is the realization that, because the loans made by theDepartment of Education—which make up the vast majorityof student loans outstanding—were already funded when theloans were originated, the new costs of cancelling these loans arelimited to the interest payments on the securities issued at thattime. An alternative route, which some have advocated, involvesthe Federal Reserve buying up student loan debt and warehousing the losses on its own balance sheet. We consider this optionbelow, noting that this avenue would most likely require authorization from Congress. Importantly, we also show that any program led by the Federal Reserve results in the same consequencesfor the federal government’s budget position as a governmentled program—that is, there is no “free lunch” that avoids thebudgetary implications of cancelling student debt.We also simulated the student debt cancellation programusing two macroeconometric models to examine the implications of cancellation and incorporate feedback effects that gobeyond the balance sheet analysis. The first-round effect of student debt cancellation is an increase in the wealth and disposable income of student loan borrowers. These effects translateto higher spending in a variety of consumption and investmentcategories, which represent greater economic activity and produce additional income, jobs, and tax revenue. We relied on twomacroeconomic models to simulate these effects: Ray Fair ofYale University’s US Macroeconomic Model (“the Fair model”)and Moody’s US Macroeconomic Model, the forecasting modelused by Moody’s and Economy.com. The Fair model and theMoody’s model share a Keynesian short-run theoretical foundation. In the long run, however, the assumed relationships differ, as Moody’s takes on a “Classical core” while the Fair modelLevy Economics Institute of Bard College7

remains fundamentally Keynesian. In addition to two modelswith distinct foundational assumptions, we also implementedtwo alternative assumptions about the Federal Reserve’s interest rate response to the debt cancellation stimulus. The use ofmodels with contrasting long-run theoretical foundations andalternative scenarios demonstrates the robustness of the resultsin this report, and also allows us to present a plausible range foreach of the estimated effects of a federally financed student debtcancellation.A program to cancel student debt executed in 2017 resultsin an increase in real GDP, a decrease in the average unemployment rate, and little to no inflationary pressure over the 10-yearhorizon of our simulations, while interest rates increase onlymodestly. Our results show that the positive feedback effects ofstudent debt cancellation could add on average between 86 bil-0.65 and 0.75 percent of GDP per year. However, the more relevant figures for the annual impact on the federal deficit fall in arange between 0.29 and 0.37 percent of GDP—this accounts forthe fact that, for the Department of Education loans, only debtservice on the securities originally issued will add to currentdeficits and the national debt. The simulations, by their nature,assume the full costs of the foregone principal and interest onthe Department of Education loans are incurred in the cancellation. In Section 3 and Appendix B, we explain the reasons for thisassumption embedded in the simulations (which generates estimates of budget impacts relative to a no-cancellation baselinescenario) and how the lower, more relevant figures (estimatesof budget impacts relative to current deficit and debt levels) arearrived at. Only the Fair model enables forecasts of state-levelbudget positions, and we find improvements in states’ budgetlion and 108 billion per year to the economy. Associated withthis new economic activity, job creation rises and the unemployment rate declines.The macroeconomic models used in these simulationsassume an essentially mechanical Federal Reserve response tolower unemployment. Suppressing this response—in otherwords, assuming the Fed does not raise its interest rate target—provides an upper bound for the range of possible outcomesassociated with more nuanced central bank policy. In fact, bothmodels forecast little to no additional inflation resulting fromthe cancellation of student debt. In the Fair model, inflationpeaks at an additional 0.3 percent and turns negative after 2020,meaning that debt cancellation reduces inflation in later years.In the Moody’s model, the inflationary effects are never higherthan 0.09 percent throughout the period. These forecasts suggest that there is room for flexibility in the assumptions madeabout Federal Reserve tactics as a response to debt cancellation.Since even the largest effect on inflation in a single year is oflittle macroeconomic significance, it is arguable that the Fedwould not react to the student debt cancellation program byraising its target interest rate.Student debt cancellation is a large-scale program in whichthe government must repay privately held loans and foregointerest rate payments on the loan portfolio of the Departmentof Education. It is reasonable to expect such a program to add tothe federal government’s budget deficit, absent extraordinarilystrong feedback effects from the program’s macroeconomicstimulus. Our simulations show that student debt cancellation raises the federal budget deficit moderately. The averageimpacts on the federal deficit in the simulations are betweenpositions as a result of the stimulus effects of the debt cancellation. These improvements will reduce the need for states to raisetaxes or cut spending in the event of future recessions.It is important to note that the macroeconomic modelsused in this report cannot capture all of the positive socioeconomic effects associated with cancelling student loan debt. Newresearch from academics and experts has demonstrated therelationships between student debt and business formation, college completion, household formation, and credit scores. Thesecorrelations suggest that student debt cancellation could generate substantial stimulus effects in addition to those that emergefrom our simulations, while improving the financial positionsof households.Our analysis proceeds in three sections. Section 1, “TheEconomic Opportunity of Student Debt Cancellation,” exploresthe US context of student borrowing, including reductions inpublic investment in higher education and the rising cost ofa college degree, the social costs of rising debt, and the distributional implications of debt and debt cancellation. Section2, “The Mechanics of Student Debt Cancellation,” explainsthe instruments of debt relief, whether enacted by the federal government or its central bank (the Federal Reserve), anddemonstrates the balance sheet effects of debt cancellation onthe government, the Federal Reserve, banks, borrowers, andprivate lenders. Finally, Section 3, “Simulating Student DebtCancellation,” measures the effects of the program on key macroeconomic variables using simulations in two models—theFair model and Moody’s model—under alternative assumptions, and examines the costs and benefits of student debt reliefthat are omitted from the models.8Student Debt Cancellation Report 2018

Section 1: The EconomicOpportunity of Student DebtCancellationIn the United States, attaining a college degree has long beenviewed as a safe investment for individuals and for the nationas a whole. The funding of higher education from both publicand private sources exemplifies the joint character of this investment, and a strong system of public education has conferredbroad social and economic benefits. Yet over the past threedecades our common commitment to education has brokendown. American households increasingly shoulder the burdenof financing higher education. This private financing of highereducation requires a growing share of household consumption and investment spending, drawing resources away fromother sectors such as housing and other markets for consumerfinance. Most students today meet the growing cost by taking on debt. As a result of the shifting financial responsibilityfor higher education, student debt is at record highs. Collegegraduates begin their careers with debt payments that absorbincome and supplant other important early-adulthood investment opportunities. Moreover, the increasingly private responsibility for financing higher education diverts attention fromthe important social benefits of an educated population as economic decisions focus more and more on individual returns.Thus, the debt-based system of higher education finance comesat a larger cost: student debt limits the economic opportunitiesof today’s young people, depletes other forms of consumer andinvestment spending in the economy, and undermines the commonly shared gains that derive from an educated workforce andcitizenry.Social Investment in Higher EducationThe individual benefits of a college degree are widely acknowledged, but the increasing focus on individual financing haslargely neglected similar calculations on the social scale. Thereturns to individuals accrue in terms of employment opportunities and lifetime earnings. Comparing workers with abachelor’s degree to those whose education ended with a highschool diploma shows that a postsecondary credential is moreand more valuable, leading college graduates to higher lifetime incomes and lower unemployment rates relative to thosewithout a degree (Vandenbroucke 2015). However, mountingeconomic evidence suggests the labor market is increasinglycredentialized, and hence persistent higher education wage gapsreflect worsening outcomes for those without degrees—thus thegrowing imperative of obtaining a higher education credential,even as the costs are shifted to individual students.These benefits, combined with wider opportunities in boththe labor market and the higher education system for womenand people of color, have driven rates of college attainmentamong adults in the United States from less than one in ten 50years ago to a record high of approximately one in three today(US Census Bureau, Table A-2). Similarly, higher education is avaluable social investment, with positive spillover effects fromgenerating new knowledge and expanding skills at both localand national levels. The higher incomes associated with a college degree represent greater productive capacity and a highervalue of human capital stock economy-wide. These direct andoften clearly monetized gains accrue in terms of skills, income,and increased productivity that contribute to GDP growth andrising living standards for the entire economy.Recent research from the Organisation for EconomicCo-operation and Development (OECD 2015) shows that thesocial benefits of public spending on higher education far outweigh the public costs. In the United States, lower unemployment rates, higher tax revenues, and other social contributionsassociated with educated workers result in net social benefitsworth between two and five times the dollar amount of publicspending on higher education. Yet even these impressive figurescapture only part of the gains. Research shows that better-educated people live longer, healthier lives, commit fewer crimes,and are more civically engaged (OECD 2015). Higher education plays a key role in our nation’s socioeconomic mobilityand, as a result, access to higher education is a crucial facet ofequality of opportunity for young people and families hopingto achieve a better life. Finally, an increasingly productive andhighly educated society yields intergenerational advantages, asthe associated institutions, networks, and aptitudes are passeddown over time. Accounting for each of these benefits wouldraise estimates of the reward for society beyond the OECD figures by reducing public expenditures on health care and crime,improving quality of life, and contributing to equality of opportunity and political stability.The social benefits of increasing educational attainmentare dispersed, generating returns even for those individuals whochoose to forego a college degree. These dispersed benefits inLevy Economics Institute of Bard College9

the market for higher education are a classic example of positive externalities—benefits accruing as a result of exchange thatare not taken into account by private buyers and sellers. Likeother markets where positive externalities exist, the omission ofsocial benefits in individual cost/benefit calculations results in amarket failure. A higher education market composed of purelyprivate exchange would lead to conditions of chronic underinvestment. The key to avoiding a market failure and capturingthe social returns of an educated population is public support.The United States has a history of financing higher education inpartnership with students and their families, with the majorityof college students attending public institutions supported bystate and federal spending (NCES 2015, Table 303.7). Yet overrecent decades that partnership has devolved and individualsare taking on a growing share of the cost of higher education.The rising individual cost burden of attaining a collegedegree also has spillover effects on the rest of the economy.With declining state support and a persistent social and economic demand for college credentials, postsecondary education is increasingly financed through debt. This debt weighs onhousehold finances, affecting the consumption and investmentopportunities of borrowers, with ripple effects across other consumer debt markets and beyond. Debt service payments reducedisposable income and consumption spending. College graduates focused on paying down debt are putting off other investments, like buying a home or starting a family—or taking onyet more debt to obtain graduate degrees that are increasinglynecessary as the labor market credentializes. And as the individual investment perspective drives a greater share of the market, society risks losing valuable benefits to a higher educationmarket failure.The current state of student debtMore than ever before, Americans recognize higher educationas an important milestone on the pathway toward prosperityand financial stability. As a result, waning public support forhigher education and rising individual costs have promptedthe growth of student debt to record levels. According to theFederal Reserve (2016), outstanding student loan debt totaled 1.35 trillion as of the first quarter of 2016—an amount 28 percent greater than all motor vehicle loans and 40 percent greaterthan the value of outstanding student loan debt just five yearsago. The vast majority of this debt originates from federal lending, with the private student loan market accounting for just7.6 percent ( 99.7 million) of all student debt (MeasureOne10Student Debt Cancellation Report 2018Figure 1.1 Percentage of Undergraduate Seniors WhoReceived Student Loans2011–12Average Loan Balance 26,3001999–2000Average Loan Balance 22,1001989–90Average Loan Balance 15,2000102030405060Percent708090100Students Who Received Student LoansStudents Who Never Received Student LoansSource: NCES 2014 Digest of Education Statistics, Table 331.95Table 1.1 Share Borrowing and Cumulative AmountBorrowed for Undergraduate Education among Thosewith Debt, by Race/Ethnicity and by Institution Type forGraduating Seniors, 2011–12ShareBorrowingCumulativeBorrowingTotal69% 29,384Race/Ethnicity (with multiple)White67.5% 29,065Black or African American84.2% 33,015Hispanic or Latino71.9% 29,517Asian American47.2% 23,135American Indian or Alaska Native61.5%‡Native Hawaiian/Other Pacific Islander‡‡Other81.0% 28,052More Than One Race‡‡Institution TypePublic Four-Year64.1% 25,458Private Not-for-Profit Four-Year73.1% 32,388Public Two-Year‡‡Private For-Profit87.2% 40,025Others/Attended More Than One School71.8% 29,444‡ Reporting standards not met.Source: NCES 2011–12 National Postsecondary Student Aid Study (NPSAS:12)2015). The growth in borrowing occurred as more college students turned to loans to finance their education and the typical loan amount per borrower increased (see Figure 1.1). In the1989–90 academic year, 50.5 percent of undergraduate seniorsages 18–24 relied on student loans for some portion of theircollege costs. The average loan amount among those borrowing was 15,200. At the end of the 2011–12 academic year, 68

percent of graduating seniors left college with some studentdebt and the average balance rose to over 26,000 (NCES 2014,Table 331.95). The growing reliance on student loans marks animportant generational shift as today’s graduates begin theirworking lives hampered by debt payments that preclude othereconomic opportunities.Today the majority of college students incur student debt,but the degree of exposure differs by critical demographic factors such as race and ethnicity and the type of academic institution attended (Table 1.1). Students at public institutions wereless likely to borrow than those at private for-profit or not-forprofit institutions, but even at public schools most studentsrelied on loans to some extent (NCES 2013). Black and Latinostudents are the most likely to take out loans and borrow greateramounts. In 2011–12, 84 percent of black graduating seniorscodes with high minority populations are significantly morelikely to be burdened by their student debt payments (as a percentage of their income), and thus to go delinquent on theirloans.The growth in student loan debt is driven by several important factors, including a rapid rise in the cost of attaining adegree (Figure 1.2) at the same time a college education becameincreasingly associated with individual advancement and economic success. After remaining relatively stable for decades,average tuition and fees at public, undergraduate, four-yearinstitutions rose 156 percent between the 1990–91 and 2014–15academic years. The total price tag, including tuition, fees, androom and board, doubled over the period to reach 18,632 in2014–15 (NCES 2015, Table 330.10).The impact of this growth in the cost of college was magni-had borrowed for college, as had 72

The government cancels the Department of Education's loans as borrowers' payments come due 21 Government-led debt cancellation where the government assumes payments on student loans issued by 22 private investors Government-led debt cancellation where the government simultaneously purchases and then cancels loans owned 24 by private investors

Related Documents:

May 02, 2018 · D. Program Evaluation ͟The organization has provided a description of the framework for how each program will be evaluated. The framework should include all the elements below: ͟The evaluation methods are cost-effective for the organization ͟Quantitative and qualitative data is being collected (at Basics tier, data collection must have begun)

Silat is a combative art of self-defense and survival rooted from Matay archipelago. It was traced at thé early of Langkasuka Kingdom (2nd century CE) till thé reign of Melaka (Malaysia) Sultanate era (13th century). Silat has now evolved to become part of social culture and tradition with thé appearance of a fine physical and spiritual .

On an exceptional basis, Member States may request UNESCO to provide thé candidates with access to thé platform so they can complète thé form by themselves. Thèse requests must be addressed to esd rize unesco. or by 15 A ril 2021 UNESCO will provide thé nomineewith accessto thé platform via their émail address.

̶The leading indicator of employee engagement is based on the quality of the relationship between employee and supervisor Empower your managers! ̶Help them understand the impact on the organization ̶Share important changes, plan options, tasks, and deadlines ̶Provide key messages and talking points ̶Prepare them to answer employee questions

Dr. Sunita Bharatwal** Dr. Pawan Garga*** Abstract Customer satisfaction is derived from thè functionalities and values, a product or Service can provide. The current study aims to segregate thè dimensions of ordine Service quality and gather insights on its impact on web shopping. The trends of purchases have

Chính Văn.- Còn đức Thế tôn thì tuệ giác cực kỳ trong sạch 8: hiện hành bất nhị 9, đạt đến vô tướng 10, đứng vào chỗ đứng của các đức Thế tôn 11, thể hiện tính bình đẳng của các Ngài, đến chỗ không còn chướng ngại 12, giáo pháp không thể khuynh đảo, tâm thức không bị cản trở, cái được

Le genou de Lucy. Odile Jacob. 1999. Coppens Y. Pré-textes. L’homme préhistorique en morceaux. Eds Odile Jacob. 2011. Costentin J., Delaveau P. Café, thé, chocolat, les bons effets sur le cerveau et pour le corps. Editions Odile Jacob. 2010. Crawford M., Marsh D. The driving force : food in human evolution and the future.

Le genou de Lucy. Odile Jacob. 1999. Coppens Y. Pré-textes. L’homme préhistorique en morceaux. Eds Odile Jacob. 2011. Costentin J., Delaveau P. Café, thé, chocolat, les bons effets sur le cerveau et pour le corps. Editions Odile Jacob. 2010. 3 Crawford M., Marsh D. The driving force : food in human evolution and the future.